Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
Charges for Hydropower Projects' Use of Federal Lands Need to Be Reassessed
Gao ID: GAO-03-383 May 20, 2003
Hydropower projects generate power valued at billions of dollars. For projects located on federal lands, FERC is required to assess "reasonable annual charges" to use these lands. FERC agrees that fair market value is the most reasonable basis for assessing these charges. This report examines FERC's annual charge system and the extent to which it reflects the federal lands' contributions to hydropower. GAO described and assessed FERC's annual charge system, estimated the fair market value for the use of federal lands, and discussed the implications of higher charges on consumers and project owners.
Since 1987, FERC's charges for hydropower projects on federal lands have been based on a linear rights-of-way fee schedule that was originally used to determine the annual fees other agencies charged for the rights to locate, among other things, powerlines, pipelines, and communication lines on federal lands--uses that are generally less valuable than hydropower. FERC chose this system primarily because it was simple and predictable and would not subject the commission to appeals from the electricity industry. However, this system has no relationship to the economic benefit of the federal lands used to produce hydropower. In addition, in implementing this system, FERC does not ensure that (1) the charges it collects achieve the hydropower annual charge program objectives, (2) it has accurate information on the amount of federal lands licensees use, or (3) its billing system collects all charges due the federal government for the use of its lands. The annual charges FERC currently collects from hydropower projects for the use of federal lands are significantly less than the annual fair market value of these lands. For this report, GAO defined this value as the value of the annual economic contribution that the use of federal lands makes to the production of hydropower. According to GAO's analysis, FERC is receiving less than 2 percent of the annual fair market value for the use of these lands. In performing its analysis, GAO examined multiple electricity market scenarios, including three that estimated the value of federal lands using actual industry data from three recent years. Under these scenarios, the fair market value for the use of federal lands by GAO's sample of hydropower projects is at least $157 million annually and, under some market conditions, hundreds of millions of dollars more. In comparison, FERC collected about $2.7 million in annual charges from these projects in 2002. GAO reached these conclusions on the basis of its analysis of a stratified random sample of 24 projects that use federal lands. This sample was drawn from 56 projects that collectively account for about 90 percent of the hydropower produced on federal lands. Although this sample of 24 projects was not representative of all hydropower projects on federal lands, these projects produced about 60 percent of all electricity generated by FERC-licensed hydropower projects that use federal land and represent about 35 percent of all federal lands used for hydropower production. If FERC decides to collect annual charges that more closely reflect the fair market value for the use of federal lands, the implications of such a decision for consumers and hydropower project owners would depend on (1) how much of the fair market value FERC chooses to recover and how it decides to implement these higher charges and (2) whether the affected electricity market is still fully regulated or has been restructured.
Recommendations
Our recommendations from this work are listed below with a Contact for more information. Status will change from "In process" to "Open," "Closed - implemented," or "Closed - not implemented" based on our follow up work.
Director:
Team:
Phone:
GAO-03-383, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission: Charges for Hydropower Projects' Use of Federal Lands Need to Be Reassessed
This is the accessible text file for GAO report number GAO-03-383
entitled 'Federal Energy Regulatory Commission: Charges for Hydropower
Projects' Use of Federal Lands Need to Be Reassessed' which was
released on May 20, 2003.
This text file was formatted by the U.S. General Accounting Office
(GAO) to be accessible to users with visual impairments, as part of a
longer term project to improve GAO products' accessibility. Every
attempt has been made to maintain the structural and data integrity of
the original printed product. Accessibility features, such as text
descriptions of tables, consecutively numbered footnotes placed at the
end of the file, and the text of agency comment letters, are provided
but may not exactly duplicate the presentation or format of the printed
version. The portable document format (PDF) file is an exact electronic
replica of the printed version. We welcome your feedback. Please E-mail
your comments regarding the contents or accessibility features of this
document to Webmaster@gao.gov.
This is a work of the U.S. government and is not subject to copyright
protection in the United States. It may be reproduced and distributed
in its entirety without further permission from GAO. Because this work
may contain copyrighted images or other material, permission from the
copyright holder may be necessary if you wish to reproduce this
material separately.
Report to Congressional Requesters:
May 2003:
FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION:
Charges for Hydropower Projects' Use of Federal Lands Need to Be
Reassessed:
GAO-03-383:
GAO Highlights:
Highlights of GAO-03-383, a report to Congressional Requesters
Why GAO Did This Study:
Hydropower projects generate power valued at billions of dollars. For
projects located on federal lands, FERC is required to assess
’reasonable annual charges“ to use these lands. FERC agrees that fair
market value is the most reasonable basis for assessing these charges.
This report examines FERC‘s annual charge system and the extent to
which it reflects the federal lands‘ contributions to hydropower. GAO
described and assessed FERC‘s annual charge system, estimated the fair
market value for the use of federal lands, and discussed the
implications of higher charges on consumers and project owners.
What GAO Found:
Since 1987, FERC‘s charges for hydropower projects on federal lands
have been based on a linear rights-of-way fee schedule that was
originally used to determine the annual fees other agencies charged
for the rights to locate, among other things, powerlines, pipelines,
and communication lines on federal lands”uses that are generally less
valuable than hydropower. FERC chose this system primarily because it
was simple and predictable and would not subject the commission to
appeals from the electricity industry. However, this system has no
relationship to the economic benefit of the federal lands used to
produce hydropower. In addition, in implementing this system, FERC
does not ensure that (1) the charges it collects achieve the
hydropower annual charge program objectives, (2) it has accurate
information on the amount of federal lands licensees use, or (3) its
billing system collects all charges due the federal government for the
use of its lands.
The annual charges FERC currently collects from hydropower projects
for the use of federal lands are significantly less than the annual
fair market value of these lands. For this report, GAO defined this
value as the value of the annual economic contribution that the use of
federal lands makes to the production of hydropower. According to
GAO‘s analysis, FERC is receiving less than 2 percent of the annual
fair market value for the use of these lands. In performing its
analysis, GAO examined multiple electricity market scenarios,
including three that estimated the value of federal lands using actual
industry data from three recent years. Under these scenarios, the fair
market value for the use of federal lands by GAO‘s sample of
hydropower projects is at least $157 million annually and, under some
market conditions, hundreds of millions of dollars more. In
comparison, FERC collected about $2.7 million in annual charges from
these projects in 2002.
GAO reached these conclusions on the basis of its analysis of a
stratified random sample of 24 projects that use federal lands. This
sample was drawn from 56 projects that collectively account for about
90 percent of the hydropower produced on federal lands. Although this
sample of 24 projects was not representative of all hydropower
projects on federal lands, these projects produced about 60 percent of
all electricity generated by FERC-licensed hydropower projects that
use federal land and represent about 35 percent of all federal lands
used for hydropower production.
If FERC decides to collect annual charges that more closely reflect
the fair market value for the use of federal lands, the implications
of such a decision for consumers and hydropower project owners would
depend on (1) how much of the fair market value FERC chooses to
recover and how it decides to implement these higher charges and (2)
whether the affected electricity market is still fully regulated or
has been restructured.
What GAO Recommends:
FERC should reconsider its current system and develop new strategies
and options for assessing annual charges that are proportionate with
the economic benefits conveyed to hydropower licensees.
While FERC is developing this strategy, it should better manage its
current system by verifying the amount of federal lands hydropower
projects use and resolving discrepancies among its multiple billing
and land databases.
In its comments, FERC disagreed with our valuation of federal lands
but agreed with our recommendations to resolve discrepancies among its
databases.
The National Hydropower Association also disagreed with our valuation
of federal lands.
www.gao.gov/cgi-bin/getrpt?GAO-03-383.
To view the full report, including the scope
and methodology, click on the link above.
For more information, contact Barry T. Hill at (202) 512-3841.
[End of section]
Letter:
Results in Brief:
Background:
FERC's System for Determining Annual Charges Is Based on Values
for Rights-of-Way, Not Hydropower:
Many Federal Lands in Our Sample Are Significantly More Valuable Than
FERC's Current Charges Suggest:
Effect of Higher Annual Charges on Consumers and Project Owners Will
Depend on FERC's Implementation and the Regulatory Environment:
FERC's Future Ability to Increase Annual Charges Could Be Limited by
Electricity Market Restructuring:
Conclusion:
Recommendations for Executive Action:
Agency and Industry Comments:
Scope and Methodology:
Appendixes:
Appendix I: Estimating the Fair Market Value of Federal Land
Used to Produce Hydropower:
Appendix II: Net Benefits Analysis for Each of the 24 Projects in
Our Sample:
Appendix III: Comments from the Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission:
Appendix IV: Comments from the National Hydropower Association:
Appendix V: Comments from the Department of the Interior:
Appendix VI: GAO Contact and Staff Acknowledgments:
Tables:
Table 1: Hydropower Projects Included in Our Sample:
Table 2: The Estimated Annual Value for the Use of Federal Lands for
Each of the 24 Projects in Our Sample for 1998, 1999, and 2000; and
FERC Annual Charges for 2002:
Table 3: Results of Our Sensitivity Analyses of Each of the 24 Projects
in Our Sample--1999, 1999 with a Change in Price, and 1999 with a
Change in Quantity:
Table 4: The Estimated Annual Value for the Use of Federal Lands for
Each of the 24 Projects in Our Sample for 2003, and FERC Annual Charges
for 2002:
Table 5: Numeric Example of Summary Net Benefits Calculations:
Table 6: Profiles of Our Sample of 24 Hydropower Projects:
Table 7: Prices Used to Value Hydropower for Our Sample of 24 Projects::
Table 8: Bath County, FERC License No. 2716:
Table 9: Big Creek 1&2, FERC License No. 2175:
Table 10: Bliss, FERC License No. 1975:
Table 11: Boundary, FERC License No. 2144:
Table 12: California Aqueduct, FERC License No. 2426:
Table 13: Coosa River, FERC License No. 2146:
Table 14: Don Pedro, FERC License No. 2299:
Table 15: Feather River, FERC License No. 2100:
Table 16: Haas-Kings River, FERC License No. 1988:
Table 17: Hells Canyon, FERC License No. 1971:
Table 18: Kerckhoff 1&2, FERC License No. 96:
Table 19: Kerr, FERC License No. 5:
Table 20: North Fork, FERC License No. 2195:
Table 21: North Umpqua, FERC License No. 1927:
Table 22: Noxon Rapids, FERC License No. 2075:
Table 23: Pit River, FERC License No. 233:
Table 24: Priest Rapids, FERC License No. 2114:
Table 25: Rock Island, FERC License No. 943:
Table 26: Rocky Reach, FERC License No. 2145:
Table 27: Skagit River, FERC License No. 553:
Table 28: Swift, FERC License No. 2111:
Table 29: Thompson Falls, FERC License No. 1869:
Table 30: Upper American River Project, FERC License No. 2101:
Table 31: Upper North Fork Feather River, FERC License No. 2105:
Figures :
Figure 1: Locations of the 56 Largest FERC-Licensed Projects That Use
Federal Lands for Hydropower Production:
Figure 2: The Estimated Annual Value for the Use of Federal Lands
Compared with FERC's Annual Charges:
Figure 3: Illustration of the Cost to Produce Hydropower Before and
After a Sale That Occurs as Part of Restructuring:
Figure 4: The Net Benefits Methodology:
Abbreviations:
BCPS: Bath County Pumped Storage:
BLM: Bureau of Land Management:
CAPX: California Power Exchange:
CCCT: combined-cycle combustion turbine:
EIA: Energy Information Administration:
FERC: Federal Energy Regulatory Commission:
GAO: General Accounting Office:
ID: irrigation district:
IOU: investor-owned utility:
IPP: independent power producer:
kwh: kilowatt-hour:
Muni: municipality:
NBV: net book value:
NHA: National Hydropower Association:
O&M: operations and maintenance:
PJM-WH: Pennsylvania, New Jersey, Maryland-Western Hub:
PUD: Public Utility District:
RCLPD: replacement cost less physical depreciation:
SERC: Southeastern Electric Reliability Council:
WECC: Western Electricity Coordinating Council:
Letter May 20, 2003:
The Honorable David L. Hobson
Chairman
The Honorable Peter J. Visclosky
Ranking Minority Member
Subcommittee on Energy and Water Development
Committee on Appropriations
House of Representatives:
The Honorable Charles H. Taylor
Chairman, Subcommittee on Interior
Committee on Appropriations
House of Representatives:
The Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC)--an independent
fivemember commission appointed by the President and confirmed by
the Senate--issues licenses to construct and operate many nonfederally
owned hydropower projects, including 173 located on federal lands.
These 173 projects generate electricity worth billions of
dollars annually.[Footnote 1]
The Federal Power Act requires FERC to establish and collect reasonable
annual charges for the use of these federal lands. In doing so, FERC
must take into account the effect of these charges on consumer rates
and hydropower development. The act does not prescribe what value
represents a reasonable annual charge; however, one criterion generally
used for valuing land in both the public and private sectors is the
land's fair market value. In implementing the annual charge
requirement, FERC stated that using the fair market value of the land
is the most reasonable method for compensating the government for the
use of its lands. Fair market value is generally defined as the price
agreed to by a willing buyer and a willing seller, where both parties
have reasonable knowledge of the relevant facts. Since federal lands
are not generally sold, our estimate of fair market value in this
report refers to the value of the annual economic contribution federal
lands make to the production of hydropower.
The federal lands used to generate hydropower have considerable
value because of the advantages hydropower has over other sources
of electricity and because of the scarcity of lands that can be used
to generate hydropower. Compared with other sources of electricity
generation, hydropower is inexpensive to produce, its production can
be increased quickly in periods of peak demand, and it produces no
air pollution or radioactive wastes. There are also some disadvantages
to hydropower, such as the fact that (1) the amount of power produced
is limited to the amount of water available and (2) future regulatory
actions established through the relicensing of hydropower projects
could, among other things, limit the future quantity--or increase the
cost--of hydropower produced at some projects. While hydropower has
some advantages over other sources of electricity generation, lands
that are suitable for producing large amounts of hydropower are scarce.
These lands have unique characteristics, such as steep canyons, flowing
rivers, and/or the capability of storing large volumes of water. The
more hydropower the land is capable of producing, the greater the value
of the land.
The U.S. electricity industry is currently undergoing substantial
restructuring--from an industry that has historically been highly
regulated by federal and state governments to one that operates in a
more competitive environment. For example, FERC has historically
approved wholesale electricity prices--the prices charged when
utilities buy and sell power from other utilities within the same
region of the country--and state regulators have approved retail
electricity prices, such as those charged to residential and industrial
consumers, principally on the basis of production costs. However, some
states have recently restructured their retail electricity markets by
allowing competition in the generation segment of the industry. In some
cases, regulated utilities were required to sell many or all of their
power plants in order to foster competition. In restructured markets,
prices are determined by supply and demand. As a matter of policy, FERC
encourages the movement toward greater competition in wholesale energy
markets. While some states have plans to move in this direction, others
do not.
As requested, this report addresses FERC's system for developing
reasonable annual charges for the use of federal lands and the extent
to which this system reflects the contribution these lands make to the
generation of electricity. Specifically, we (1) describe the system
FERC currently uses for determining reasonable annual charges for the
use of federal lands by hydropower projects and assess FERC's
management of that system; (2) estimate the fair market value for the
use of these federal lands and compare that value with the annual
charges FERC currently collects for the use of these lands; (3) discuss
the implications for consumers and hydropower project owners of having
FERC collect annual charges that more closely reflect the fair market
value of the land; and (4) discuss the implications of FERC's not
acting to collect charges that more closely reflect fair market value
until after restructuring of electricity markets occurs.
To determine the fair market value of federal lands used by hydropower
projects, we examined a stratified random sample of 24 FERC-licensed
hydropower projects from a group of 56 projects. These 56 projects
collectively account for about 90 percent of the hydropower produced on
federal lands. Although our sample of 24 projects was not
representative of all hydropower projects on federal lands, these
projects produced about 60 percent of all the electricity generated by
the FERC-licensed hydropower projects that used federal land and
represent about 35 percent of all federal lands used to produce
hydropower. We estimated the annual value of the federal lands in our
sample of projects using a technique known as a "net benefits
analysis." A net benefits analysis estimates the difference between the
value of the power produced and the cost to produce it. This difference
is an estimate of the land's annual fair market value. We used the net
benefits approach because there is no active market for renting lands
for hydropower that would provide comparable values for these lands.
With the exception of federal lands and lands within Indian
reservations, FERC generally requires licensees to either own the land
within their project boundaries or secure the land through an easement
in perpetuity.
We applied our net benefits methodology to our sample of projects under
six different scenarios. First, we conducted a net benefits analysis on
the basis of actual industry data for 3 recent years--1998, 1999, and
2000. In general, to conduct these three analyses, we estimated the
value of the power by multiplying data on the average wholesale price
of electricity by the amount of electricity actually generated. To
estimate the cost of producing that power, we estimated project capital
costs, including a rate of return on the investment, and added this
estimate to data on actual operating costs for the same period. Second,
to demonstrate how our analysis can be affected by changes in the price
and quantity of power produced in any given year, we performed two
sensitivity analyses on our 1999 results--one for changes in price and
one for changes in quantity. Finally, because the wholesale price of
electricity was extremely volatile at times during the 3-year period--
1998, 1999, and 2000--we estimated what the fair market value of these
lands might be in 2003 using (1) average annual generation data for
1995 through 2000 and operating cost data for 1998 through 2000,
(2) estimates of capital costs for 2003, and (3) estimates of the long-
term value of electricity. For comparison purposes, we adjusted all
values to 2002 constant dollars. We discussed our approach and the
results of our analysis with FERC, representatives of the hydropower
projects we sampled, industry associations, state governments, consumer
advocate groups, and several other federal agencies. Some of these
representatives expressed concerns about using this method, preferring
instead FERC's current method because of its simplicity and relatively
low charges. We discuss additional details on our use of the net
benefits analysis in appendix I.
Results in Brief:
Although FERC has acknowledged that using fair market value is the most
reasonable method for compensating the federal government for the use
of its land, since 1987, FERC has used a "linear rights-of-way" fee
schedule to determine annual charges for federal land used by
hydropower projects. This system--designed by the U.S. Department of
Agriculture's Forest Service and the Department of the Interior's
Bureau of Land Management--was originally used to determine the annual
fees the two agencies should charge for the rights to locate, among
other things, power lines, pipelines, and communications lines on
federal land. The agencies base their specific fees on the number of
acres used. In implementing the linear rights-of-way system, FERC
acknowledged that hydropower project uses are more valuable than
rights-of-way. As a result, to capture these higher values, FERC
doubled the per-acre fees in the rights-of-way schedule and multiplied
that amount by the number of acres that were identified as being
federally owned within the hydropower project's designated boundary.
FERC then collected these amounts as annual charges for the use of
federal lands by hydropower projects. FERC stated that the purpose of
the 1987 annual charge system was to "establish a fair market rate" for
the use of federal lands. However, this system has no relationship to
the economic benefit of the federal lands used to produce hydropower.
In addition, according to FERC's former Director of Hydropower, FERC
chose this fee system primarily because it was a simple and predictable
method to use and would not subject the commission to numerous court
challenges from the electricity industry.
Since issuing its regulations in 1987, FERC has not performed the
oversight needed to ensure that (1) the charges it is collecting meet
the hydropower annual charge program objectives, (2) it has accurate
information on the amount of federal lands used by licensees, or
(3) its billing system collects all charges that are due the federal
government for the use of its lands. Specifically, FERC has not
performed any research or analysis to assess whether its fee schedule
results in annual charges that are proportionate to the benefits
conferred. In addition, FERC allows licensees to self-report the amount
of federal acreage their projects use but does not verify any of this
information. Since FERC determines its annual charges on a per-acre
basis, having accurate and verified information on the amount of
federal lands licensees use is critical to collecting all monies that
are due the government. Finally, FERC has three separate databases it
uses to determine annual charges--two for determining the amount or
type of federal land used by a hydropower project and one for
determining the billing amount. These databases sometimes contain
conflicting information, which lead to billing errors and, in some
cases, result in FERC's not collecting all the annual charges due the
federal government.
The annual charges FERC currently collects for the use of federal lands
are significantly less than the value of the annual economic
contribution that these lands make to the production of hydropower,
according to our analysis of the 24 hydropower projects. That is, FERC
is receiving less than 2 percent of the fair market value for the use
of these lands. In total, the estimated fair market value of the
federal lands used by our sample of 24 hydropower projects is at least
$157 million annually and, under some market conditions, the value of
these lands is worth hundreds of millions of dollars more. In
comparison, FERC collected about $2.7 million in annual charges from
these projects in 2002.
If FERC decides to collect annual charges that more closely reflect the
fair market value for the use of federal lands, the implications of
such a decision for consumers and hydropower project owners would
depend on (1) how much of the fair market value FERC chooses to recover
and how it decides to implement these higher charges and (2) whether
the affected electricity market is still fully regulated or has been
restructured. First, FERC must balance any increases in charges with
the Federal Power Act's requirement to seek to avoid unreasonable
increases in consumer rates and the act's goal of encouraging the
development of hydropower. FERC may therefore decide to collect only a
portion of the fair market value of the land as an annual charge. No
matter how much more FERC decides to charge, the impact of higher
charges will depend in part on how FERC introduces them. FERC has
options to mitigate the negative effects of increasing annual charges,
such as phasing in higher charges over several years or tailoring the
implementation to accommodate changes in the regulatory structure of
the industry. Second, in a regulated market, any increases in FERC's
annual charges would most likely be passed on directly to consumers
through higher electricity rates. This impact would be most evident for
some utilities and their customers in locations such as Idaho, Oregon,
and Washington State, which rely heavily on FERC-licensed hydropower
projects to generate their electricity. Consumers who buy power from
these utilities have historically enjoyed some of the lowest
electricity rates in the country. Consequently, any increase in annual
charges to better reflect the fair market value of the federal land
would most likely increase rates to a level that would be closer to the
national average. In contrast, in a restructured environment, where
electricity rates are based on wholesale market prices, increased
annual charges are much more likely to affect the profitability of the
electric utility and its shareholders rather than consumers. In this
restructured, competitive environment, the utility may not be able to
pass on any FERC increases in annual charges to consumers. For this
reason, consumers are less likely to be affected.
If FERC decides not to collect annual charges that better reflect the
fair market value for the use of federal lands until after
restructuring occurs, it may (1) limit its opportunity to increase
charges and (2) put taxpayers at risk of losing a potential future
stream of revenue. Specifically, in restructured markets some utilities
have been required to sell their generation facilities, such as
hydropower plants, in order to increase competition. The price at which
these plants sell includes the net benefits resulting from the use of
the federal land on which the project is located. Once these plants are
sold, the federal government may have limited ability to capture these
benefits because the new owner paid a price that included the
capitalized value of the land.[Footnote 2] Any further increase in
costs, such as increased annual charges, could make the cost of the
project exceed the value of the power produced. For example, Maine,
Montana, and New York have already restructured their wholesale
electricity markets. In these states, as projects were sold, the state
or the previous owner captured all of the projects' expected
net benefits. In Montana, where projects that
included federal land were sold, the federal government did not receive
any benefits from the sale even though the federal government owned
some or most of the land on which these projects were built.
Furthermore, if FERC continues to maintain annual charges at their
current low level, this benefit to some consumers will be at the
expense of many other taxpayers, who may have to make up this lost
revenue through their taxes. As FERC has observed in connection with
annual charges assessed for the use of government dams, an "overly low
annual charge payment—ultimately places higher costs on other consumer
members of the public who must make up the difference through
their taxes."[Footnote 3]
In light of the new information we are providing on the value of the
contribution that federal lands make to the production of hydropower
and FERC's policy to make all energy markets more competitive, we are
recommending that FERC develop new strategies and options for assessing
annual charges for the use of federal lands by hydropower projects that
are proportionate with the benefits conveyed to the licensees. As FERC
develops this strategy, we also recommend that it improve the
management of its current annual charge system.
We provided FERC, the Department of the Interior, the Forest Service,
and the National Hydropower Association (NHA)--a hydropower
industry group--with a draft of this report for their review and
comment. The Forest Service declined to comment. The Department of the
Interior agreed with the report and provided some technical
clarifications and observations. FERC generally agreed with our
findings and recommendations on the conflicting information in the
databases it uses to manage its annual charge system, but generally did
not believe that our method of assessing the value of federal lands
used by hydropower projects would be appropriate. FERC also raised
concerns about using a net benefits approach as a mechanism to collect
annual charges. While we recommend that FERC reassess its current
annual charge system and look for ways to better account for the value
of federal lands, we do not specifically recommend that FERC deploy our
approach to value the land as a mechanism for collecting annual
charges. NHA disagreed with our report and raised a number of concerns
about increased annual charges. For example, NHA commented that
increased annual charges will increase electricity rates to consumers,
which could adversely affect the economy of some states that benefit
from low-priced hydropower. Our report discusses this and notes that
the impacts from increasing annual charges largely depend on (1) how
much of the land's value FERC decides to collect and how it implements
any higher charges and (2) whether the affected electricity market is
still fully regulated or has been restructured.
Background:
Hydropower projects include dams, reservoirs, stream diversion
structures, powerhouses containing turbines driven by falling water,
and transmission lines. Lands capable of producing hydropower generally
have unique characteristics, such as flowing water, steep canyons, and/
or the ability to store large volumes of water for later release
through the turbines that generate electricity. Nationwide, hydropower
projects generate about 10 percent of all electricity produced in the
United States. Federally owned and operated hydropower projects produce
approximately half of this electricity. Nearly all the remaining half
is produced by about 1,000 nonfederal hydropower projects that are
licensed by FERC, about 173 of which use at least some federal lands to
produce their hydropower.[Footnote 4] Of these 173 projects,
56 projects account for about 90 percent of the hydropower produced on
federal lands. From these 56 projects, we selected a random sample of
24 hydropower projects which are the focus of this report. As figure 1
shows, most of the projects that use federal lands are located in the
western United States due, in part, to the suitable topography found in
many western states.
Figure 1: Locations of the 56 Largest FERC-Licensed Projects That Use
Federal Lands for Hydropower Production:
[See PDF for image]
[End of figure]
Section 10(e) of the Federal Power Act requires FERC to collect
"reasonable annual charges" to compensate the federal government for
the use of its lands.[Footnote 5] FERC must balance the amount of these
annual charges with the authorizing act's requirement to seek to avoid
unreasonable increases in consumer rates and the act's goal of
encouraging the development of hydropower. The act does not require
FERC to collect the fair market value of the federal land used by FERC-
licensed hydropower projects. However, fair market value is a common
criterion used by both the public and private sectors to value lands
throughout the country, and, in implementing the act, FERC stated that
fair market value was the most reasonable method of compensating the
federal government for the use of its lands. FERC further stated,
"[r]easonable annual charges are those that
are proportionate to the value of the benefit conferred. Therefore, a
fair market value approach is consistent with the dictates of the
act."[Footnote 6] The act also prescribes how revenues from annual
charges are to be distributed: 50 percent go to the Reclamation Fund--
a fund that pays for reclamation projects, primarily in the western
United States; 37.5 percent go back to the states where the projects
are located; and 12.5 percent is deposited in the Treasury's general
fund. In addition, the act fully or partially exempts hydropower
projects owned by states or municipalities from paying annual charges
if the power is sold to the public without profit or used for
municipal purposes.
The value of any land is determined by using one of three approaches--
the comparable sales approach, the income approach, or the cost
approach. The comparable sales approach, which looks at transaction
data for comparable lands, cannot be used for hydropower projects
because (1) transaction data based on sales are not appropriate since
these data are largely based on nonhydropower uses and (2) data based
on renting or leasing nonfederal lands for hydropower uses are not
available. FERC requires licensees, as a condition of obtaining a FERC
license, to own the lands or obtain an easement in perpetuity from
another landowner in order to ensure a steady supply of hydropower.
Federal lands and some Native American lands are not subject to this
requirement; however, licensees must pay annual charges for using these
lands. When there are few or no transaction data available for
comparable sales, the income approach can be used, provided that
reliable and sufficient data are available. The income approach
determines the value of a property or a business by considering its
income-producing potential. The cost approach estimates the value of a
property by adding (1) the current cost of reconstructing or replacing
existing improvements, less physical depreciation and (2) the estimated
value of the land. While the cost approach is generally considered less
reliable than the comparable sales or income approaches, some cost
approach techniques can be used to develop information needed by the
other two approaches. For our analysis, we used a variant of the income
approach--called a net benefits approach--to determine the value of
federal lands used by a sample of hydropower projects. However, instead
of using actual income from the hydropower projects--as a traditional
income approach would do--our net benefits analysis relied on the
market prices of the hydropower produced by these projects. We used
market prices because they reflect the value of power more accurately
than electricity prices that are set through state regulatory
processes. (For more information on this approach, see app. I.):
The methodology for conducting a net benefits analysis is consistent
with standard economic theory and is based on long-established
principles in economics for valuing an asset that has unique
characteristics. Specifically, with a net benefits analysis, the value
of the land is the benefit that remains after subtracting all nonland
costs of production, including returns on the owner's investment, from
the value of the power produced. This methodology for valuing land has
been accepted and used by FERC and the electricity industry as a basis
for annual charges in certain instances in the past. For example, FERC
has approved annual charges for Native American lands occupied by
hydropower projects in which the net benefits method was a basis for
the annual charge. In addition, FERC used a similar methodology for a
period of time to determine annual charges when private operators
attached powerhouses to federal government dams to produce hydropower.
We performed our analysis on a random sample of 24 FERC-licensed
hydropower projects that use federal lands. The value of each project
varies considerably from year to year, depending on the prevailing
price of electricity, the amount of water available, and restrictions
that may be put on the project's use. In addition, each project differs
from the others according to the topography of the land and the primary
purpose of the project. For example, some projects are "run-of-the-
river" projects, meaning that they depend on stream flow to operate,
while others have large reservoirs to store water for later use.
Projects with large storage reservoirs can operate to maximize revenues
by generating power during periods of high demand when wholesale prices
are high. Run-of-the-river projects cannot do this, since they depend
on stream flow to generate power. Finally, other projects have primary
purposes other than hydropower generation, such as flood control,
irrigation, and municipal and industrial water supply. These other uses
greatly affect the net benefits of the project over the years. We did
not attempt to estimate the value of the federal lands used for
purposes other than hydropower. Table 1 presents the name, location,
and owner of each of the 24 projects included in our sample.
Table 1: Hydropower Projects Included in Our Sample:
Project (FERC license no.): Bath County (2716); Location: Virginia;
Owner: Dominion Virginia Power & Allegheny Power.
Project (FERC license no.): Big Creek 1 & 2 (2175); Location:
California; Owner: Southern California Edison.
Project (FERC license no.): Bliss (1975); Location: Idaho; Owner: Idaho
Power.
Project (FERC license no.): Boundary (2144); Location: Washington;
Owner: City of Seattle.
Project (FERC license no.): California Aqueduct (2426); Location:
California; Owner: California and Los Angeles Departments of Water.
Project (FERC license no.): Coosa River (2146); Location: Alabama;
Owner: Alabama Power.
Project (FERC license no.): Don Pedro (2299); Location: California;
Owner: Turlock and Modesto Irrigation Districts.
Project (FERC license no.): Feather River (2100); Location: California;
Owner: California Department of Water Resources.
Project (FERC license no.): Haas-Kings River (1988); Location:
California; Owner: Pacific Gas and Electric.
Project (FERC license no.): Hells Canyon (1971); Location: Idaho/
Oregon; Owner: Idaho Power.
Project (FERC license no.): Kerckhoff 1 & 2 (96); Location: California;
Owner: Pacific Gas and Electric.
Project (FERC license no.): Kerr (5); Location: Montana; Owner:
Pennsylvania Power and Light Montana.
Project (FERC license no.): North Fork (2195); Location: Oregon; Owner:
Portland General Electric.
Project (FERC license no.): North Umpqua (1927); Location: Oregon;
Owner: Pacificorp.
Project (FERC license no.): Noxon Rapids (2075); Location: Idaho/
Montana; Owner: Avista Corporation.
Project (FERC license no.): Pit River (233); Location: California;
Owner: Pacific Gas and Electric.
Project (FERC license no.): Priest Rapids (2114); Location: Washington;
Owner: Grant County Public Utility District.
Project (FERC license no.): Rock Island (943); Location: Washington;
Owner: Chelan County Public Utility District.
Project (FERC license no.): Rocky Reach (2145); Location: Washington;
Owner: Chelan County Public Utility District.
Project (FERC license no.): Skagit River (553); Location: Washington;
Owner: City of Seattle.
Project (FERC license no.): Swift (2111); Location: Washington; Owner:
Pacificorp.
Project (FERC license no.): Thompson Falls (1869); Location: Montana;
Owner: Pennsylvania Power and Light Montana.
Project (FERC license no.): Upper American River Project (2101);
Location: California; Owner: Sacramento Municipal Utility District.
Project (FERC license no.): Upper North Fork Feather River (2105);
Location: California; Owner: Pacific Gas and Electric.
Sources: FERC and the Energy Information Administration.
[End of table]
FERC's System for Determining Annual Charges Is Based on Values
for Rights-of-Way, Not Hydropower:
While FERC has recognized that using the fair market value of land is a
reasonable approach for determining annual fees, it currently uses a
fee system designed for linear rights-of-way uses to determine annual
charges for hydropower projects using federal lands. The linear rights-
of-way fee system was designed by the U.S. Forest Service and the
Bureau of Land Management (BLM) to collect fees for federal lands used
for power lines, pipelines, and communications lines. However, this
system has no relationship to the economic benefit of the federal lands
used to produce hydropower. In addition, according to FERC's former
Director of Hydropower, FERC chose to use this system because it was
simple, predictable, and would not subject the commission to numerous
court challenges from the electricity industry. This official also
stated that FERC did not have the specialized staff needed to develop
its own system. However, FERC has not diligently managed this fee
system to ensure that (1) the charges it currently collects meet the
hydropower annual charge program objectives, (2) it has accurate
information on the amount of federal lands used by licensees, or
(3) its billing system collects all charges that are due the federal
government for the use of its lands.
FERC Currently Uses a Modified Rights-of-Way Fee Schedule for
Determining Annual Charges for Hydropower Projects:
The Federal Water Power Act was passed in 1920--which became the
Federal Power Act in 1935--and since 1938 FERC has used a number of
methods for determining annual charges for the use of federal lands by
hydropower projects including appraisals and national average land
values. In the 1960s, FERC calculated annual charges based on a
national average land value. This method resulted in annual land use
charges of $10.31 per acre in 1979. In 1981, the Department of Energy's
Office of the Inspector General reported that this method resulted in
"unreasonably low and inequitable" annual charges because (1) FERC
based the charges on out-dated land value information and (2) FERC was
using land values based on a nationwide average, which led to
undervaluing many hydropower lands.[Footnote 7] In response, in 1987,
FERC amended its regulations under the Federal Power Act to, among
other things, revise its methodology for assessing federal land use
charges. Specifically, FERC implemented a modified version of the
Forest Service/BLM rights-of-way fee schedule for determining
reasonable annual charges for hydropower projects.
The Forest Service/BLM fee schedule charges annual per-acre fees on the
basis of regional land values and the number of acres used. Recognizing
that federal lands used for rights-of-way are generally less valuable
than those used for hydropower project purposes, FERC modified the
schedule by doubling the fees and then multiplying that amount by the
number of acres that were identified as being federally owned within
project boundaries. The commission reasoned that fees for rights-of-way
uses on federal lands should be lower than fees charged for hydropower
uses because land used for rights-of-way remain available for other
multiple uses--such as mining, grazing, and cutting timber--while lands
used for hydropower are not available for these types of uses. However,
FERC officials said that they have not conducted any detailed research
or analysis to determine whether doubling the fees in the rights-of-way
schedule resulted in a reasonable annual charge for the use of federal
lands for hydropower production.
The Forest Service and BLM developed their fee schedule system by
collecting market data on land values throughout the nation. Using
these data, the agencies produced a system in 1986 that based annual
fees on the number of acres used, the location of the land, and the
type of right-of-way requested. However, in 1996, we reported that
these values did not consider several factors critical to establishing
land values that reflect fair market value. Specifically, they did not
reflect what the land was being used for, the "highest and best" use of
the land, or the values of any urban uses.[Footnote 8] Forest Service
officials acknowledged that the fees were too low and said that the
data collected to generate the land values used in the fee schedule
system represent the low end of the market. According to these
officials, the agency's fee system may be collecting as little as
10 percent of the fair market value of the federal lands used for
rights-of-way purposes. While the Forest Service agreed with the
findings and recommendations of our 1996 report, to date, the agency
has yet to revise its rights-of-way fee schedule system--largely
because it has not placed a high priority on completing this task.
According to a former FERC director of hydropower, FERC adopted the
Forest Service/BLM fee schedule system to determine annual charges for
using federal lands primarily because it was simple and predictable,
and would not subject the Commission to numerous appeals from industry.
Adopting the rights-of-way fee system accomplished these goals because
it is billed on a per-acre basis, its fees are annually updated based
on the Consumer Price Index, and the fees are low enough to make court
challenges from the electricity industry unlikely. In addition, in 1987
when FERC was selecting a new fee system, it did not have the staff,
such as appraisers and economists, needed to determine the value of the
federal lands used for hydropower production and to design an original
fee system. As a result, adopting the Forest Service/BLM fee schedule
provided an opportunity to increase overall fees without having to
develop a new schedule based on hydropower land values.
FERC Has Not Diligently Managed Its Current Fee System:
Since issuing the regulations in 1987, FERC has not performed the
oversight needed to ensure that (1) the charges it collects meet the
hydropower annual charge program objectives, (2) it has accurate
information on the amount of federal lands used by licensees, or
(3) its billing system collects all charges due the federal government
for the use of its lands. Federal internal control standards require
agencies to measure and monitor program performance to be reasonably
sure that the program is meeting its objectives.[Footnote 9] However,
FERC has neither measured nor monitored its current fee system to
determine if the charges it currently collects meet program objectives.
Specifically, in the 15 years since FERC implemented the current fee
system, it has never assigned staff--such as economists and appraisers-
-to determine if the system is collecting reasonable annual charges.
Consequently, FERC cannot demonstrate whether its current annual
charges for the use of federal lands are reasonable or need adjustment.
During the course of our review, FERC's executive director agreed that
an assessment of the current system would be appropriate.
Federal internal control standards also require agencies to establish
and implement policies and procedures to reasonably ensure that valid
and reliable data are obtained on the operations of the programs they
manage. However, FERC allows licensees to self-report the total federal
acreage that they use to produce hydropower and makes no attempt to
verify this information. As a result, FERC does not know if it is
receiving valid and reliable information from the hydropower licensees.
Finally, FERC is hampered in its effort to analyze the licensees'
information because its databases contain differing and, at times,
directly conflicting information about hydropower projects on federal
lands. FERC uses at least three separate databases to determine annual
charges for the use of federal lands by hydropower projects. One
database contains information on the types of federal lands on which
the hydropower projects are located, another contains data on the
number of acres of federal land the hydropower projects use, and the
third database contains information on the billing amounts. Our
analysis of these databases showed that some projects were not billed
when they should have been while others were sent bills when they
should not have been. For example, according to FERC, project owners
are not to begin receiving bills for the use of federal lands until
they have begun construction of the hydropower project. However, we
found several instances in which FERC's databases indicate that the
agency sent bills for annual charges to applicants for hydropower
project licenses, including to some applicants whose projects were
never built. In addition, we found that FERC had not billed a very
large project in Idaho for the use of federal lands for 2 years,
resulting in a total loss in annual charges of about $30,000 for 1999
and 2000. We made numerous attempts to reconcile the inconsistent
data in FERC's multiple databases. However, most of these attempts
resulted in still more contradictions concerning what information was
correct. Consequently, while we have identified several problems
with FERC's billing system, we could not determine the extent of FERC's
billing problems.
Many Federal Lands in Our Sample Are Significantly More Valuable Than
FERC's Current Charges Suggest:
FERC's annual charges are significantly less than the value of the
annual economic contribution that federal lands make to the production
of hydropower. We estimate that the annual fair market value for the
use of the federal lands used by the 24 hydropower projects in our
sample was at least $157 million. However, under FERC's modified linear
rights-of-way fee schedule, these 24 projects paid about $2.7 million
in annual charges to the federal government in 2002. Because
electricity markets are volatile, we performed a net benefits analysis
under six different market conditions, with each analysis yielding a
similar result: FERC is currently collecting annual charges that are
less than 2 percent of the annual contribution that these lands make to
the production of hydropower. This result holds true even though the
value of federal lands at individual projects varied considerably from
year to year.
Federal Lands Used by Hydropower Projects Have Significant Value:
Since wholesale electricity markets are volatile--for example, prices
are very high in some years and very low in others--we estimated the
fair market value of federal lands used by our sample of 24 hydropower
projects using six different scenarios:
* examining historical industry data for 1998, 1999, and 2000, on the
cost and value of power generated by our sample of projects;
* performing both price and quantity sensitivity analyses on the
results of our 1999 analysis, the most moderate of these years; and:
* developing an estimate of what the value of these federal lands might
be in 2003.
Figure 2 shows the results of our analysis of the six different
scenarios and compares those values with FERC's annual charges for
2002.
Figure 2: The Estimated Annual Value for the Use of Federal Lands
Compared with FERC's Annual Charges:
[See PDF for image]
Note: All data are in 2002 dollars. Also, we did not perform this
analysis for 2001 or 2002.
[End of figure]
Fair Market Value Based on Actual Data for 1998, 1999, and 2000:
According to the historical industry data we examined for 1998, 1999,
and 2000, the supply and demand for power varied substantially, and
the wholesale price of electricity varied accordingly. These data
included one year (1998) of relatively low prices and one year (2000)
of extraordinarily high prices. These changes in the wholesale price of
electricity resulted in widely differing values for the federal lands
used to produce hydropower. Specifically, the estimated value of
federal lands for our sample projects was $157 million in 1998,
$280 million in 1999, and $1.7 billion in 2000.
The estimated value for the use of federal lands during these 3 years
varied primarily in response to changes in the average wholesale price
of electricity. For example, an abundant supply of rain in portions of
the western United States in 1998 produced a supply of hydropower in
those states that was well above historical averages. The elevated
supply of electricity contributed to the relatively low wholesale
electricity prices for that year. Prices in 1999 were still somewhat
low in the West. In 2000, the wholesale price of electricity was
extremely high. Causes for the high prices included fast-growing
demand, slow-growing supply, and unusually dry and warm weather in the
region, which led to the decreased availability of electricity in
California and other western states. California state officials and
others also claimed that wholesale suppliers of electricity were
exercising market power[Footnote 10] to raise prices above competitive
levels. Table 2 shows the results of our analysis for 1998, 1999, and
2000 and compares these results with FERC's annual charges for 2002.
Each of these estimates represents the value for the use of the land
based on the price of electricity, including the potential exercise of
market power, and other market conditions that existed during that
year. In the longer term, the fair market value for the use of the land
in a competitive market cannot be consistently based on electricity
prices that are higher than the cost of alternative means of producing
electricity. As a result, the unusually high values during 2000 could
not be sustained. Such high prices would provide a strong incentive for
investors to build new electricity generating plants that would drive
down the price of electricity to the cost of that alternative source
thereby limiting the fair market value for the use of the land.
Table 2: The Estimated Annual Value for the Use of Federal Lands for
Each of the 24 Projects in Our Sample for 1998, 1999, and 2000; and
FERC Annual Charges for 2002:
Dollars in thousands.
Hells Canyon; Dollars in thousands:
1998 value
of federal lands: $111,336; 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: $145,857; 2000 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: $602,751; 2002 FERC annual charges: $371.
Boundary; Dollars in thousands: 1998 value
of federal lands: 26,606; 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 67,362; 2000 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: 297,597; 2002 FERC annual charges: 34.
Priest Rapids; Dollars in thousands: 1998 value
of federal lands: 11,665; 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 24,129; 2000 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: 92,322; 2002 FERC annual charges: 49.
Big Creek 1 & 2; Dollars in thousands: 1998 value
of federal lands: 4,865; 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 6,184; 2000 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: 96,303; 2002 FERC annual charges: 154.
Bliss; Dollars in thousands: 1998 value
of federal lands: 1,972; 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 3,399; 2000 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: 25,470; 2002 FERC annual charges: 16.
Rocky Reach; Dollars in thousands: 1998 value
of federal lands: 775; 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 1,819; 2000 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: 7,408; 2002 FERC annual charges: 3.
Rock Island; Dollars in thousands: 1998 value
of federal lands: 139; 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 596; 2000 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: 3,082; 2002 FERC annual charges: 1.
Kerr; Dollars in thousands: 1998 value
of federal lands: 102; 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 339; 2000 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: 2,563; 2002 FERC annual charges: 2.
Coosa River; Dollars in thousands: 1998 value
of federal lands: 1; 1999 value
of federal lands: ($34); 1999 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: ($86); 2000 value
of federal lands: 2002 FERC annual charges: 7.
Thompson Falls; Dollars in thousands: 1998 value
of federal lands: ($246); 1998 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 349; 2000 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: 5,772; 2002 FERC annual charges: 4.
Swift; Dollars in thousands: 1998 value
of federal lands: (338); 1998 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 318; 2000 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: 3,369; 2002 FERC annual charges: 19.
North Fork; Dollars in thousands: 1998 value
of federal lands: (408); 1998 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 832; 2000 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: 7,530; 2002 FERC annual charges: 7.
Noxon Rapids; Dollars in thousands: 1998 value
of federal lands: (715); 1998 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 410; 2000 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: 7,872; 2002 FERC annual charges: 22.
Upper North Fork Feather River; Dollars in thousands: 1998
value
of federal lands: (867); 1998 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: (517); 1999 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: 6,236; 2002 FERC annual charges: 85.
Pit River; Dollars in thousands: 1998 value
of federal lands: (1,380); 1998 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 2,535; 2000 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: 54,400; 2002 FERC annual charges: 49.
Kerckhoff 1 & 2; Dollars in thousands: 1998 value
of federal lands: (3,371); 1998 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: (4,515); 1999 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: 43,344; 2002 FERC annual charges: 25.
Don Pedro; Dollars in thousands: 1998 value
of federal lands: (5,332); 1998 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: (6,587); 1999 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: 6,905; 2002 FERC annual charges: 249.
Feather River; Dollars in thousands: 1998 value
of federal lands: (6,119); 1998 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: (6,132); 1999 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: 34,847; 2002 FERC annual charges: 9.
North Umpqua; Dollars in thousands: 1998 value
of federal lands: (13,922); 1998 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: (4,731); 1999 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: 84,937; 2002 FERC annual charges: 108.
Bath County; Dollars in thousands: 1998 value
of federal lands: (14,682); 1998 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 10,228; 2000 value
of federal lands: (1,294); 2000 value
of federal lands: 2002 FERC annual charges: 48.
Haas-Kings River; Dollars in thousands: 1998 value
of federal lands: (19,006); 1998 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: (22,205); 1999 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: 69,049; 2002 FERC annual charges: 202.
Skagit River; Dollars in thousands: 1998 value
of federal lands: (22,991); 1998 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 15,290; 2000 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: 165,137; 2002 FERC annual charges: 917.
California Aqueduct; Dollars in thousands: 1998 value
of federal lands: (27,025); 1998 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: (22,210); 1999 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: 1,793; 2002 FERC annual charges: 17.
Upper American River; Dollars in thousands: 1998 value
of federal lands: (39,178); 1998 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: (34,344); 1999 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: 68,687; 2002 FERC annual charges: 286.
Total of positive values; 1998 value
of federal lands: $157,460; 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: $279,648; 2000 value
of federal lands: 2000 value
of federal lands: $1,687,376; 2002 FERC annual charges:
$2,685.
Source: GAO.
Note: All data are in 2002 dollars. Also, as discussed in the text
below, the totals in this table do not include projects with negative
values. More detailed results of our net benefits analysis for each
project in our sample are included in app. II. Finally, FERC annual
charges are based on the number of federal acres within the designated
boundary of a hydropower project.
[End of table]
Some of the values in table 2 were negative, and we did not include
those values in the totals. The negative values are the result of our
methodology and assumptions and imply that, during the specific years
with such values, the return on investment was less than the industry
average of 7.22 percent that we assigned as part of each project's
costs.[Footnote 11] Negative values do not mean that the land is
valueless or that annual charges should be negative. Rather, the fact
that individual owners and investors choose to continue to operate
these facilities demonstrates that the land has value. For the projects
that had negative values, the return during those years was not
equivalent to what would have been earned in other investment options
with similar risk. With one exception, the projects with negative net
benefits actually had a positive estimated return on investment that
ranged from 6.8 percent to 0.1 percent.[Footnote 12] That is, for all
but one of the projects with negative net benefits, the value of power
exceeded all the costs of producing the power and still provided some
positive return on investment. If these low rates of return were to be
sustained, the owners of these projects would cease operations, and the
land for hydropower purposes would be worth zero in the worst case.
For most of the projects in our sample, the negative net benefits also
occurred because of very low electricity prices and/or overestimated
capital costs. While the cost to operate a hydropower project generally
remains stable, low electricity prices can dramatically reduce revenues
and thereby reduce or eliminate any net benefit for that year. For some
of our sample projects, a negative net benefit estimate may also mean
that the project was built for other purposes, such as irrigation. As
such, the capital costs of the project include the costs associated
with both irrigation and hydropower production. For these projects,
other purposes are emphasized over the production of hydropower. For
example, the Don Pedro Project in California is part of an irrigation
project that favors storing water for later consumption over releasing
water to generate power. As a result, the revenue potential from
hydropower operations is not maximized and the project has a minimal or
negative net benefit.
Fair Market Value of Federal Lands Sensitivity Analysis Based on Our
Analysis of 1999 Data:
We used our analysis of 1999 industry data to perform our sensitivity
analyses because that year was the most moderate of the 3 recent years
of actual historical data that we reviewed. The sensitivity analyses
illustrates the effect that uncertainty in two key variables--price and
quantity--has on our estimates of the value of federal lands. In
performing these analyses, we developed benchmarks for the (1) price
and (2) quantity of power produced. Specifically, our price benchmark
is based on estimates of the long-term value of power and our quantity
benchmark is based on historical averages. We then calculated the
change in the hydropower projects' net benefits in 1999 when
(1) wholesale prices for electricity were increased to the benchmark,
but everything else stayed the same and (2) the quantity of power
produced by the projects was decreased to the benchmark, but everything
else remained the same.
Our analysis indicated that the value of federal lands is sensitive to
changes in both the price of electricity and the amount of power
generated. For example, had average prices in 1999 been about 8 percent
higher, equivalent to the estimated cost of electricity from the lowest
cost alternative source, net benefits would have risen from
$280 million to $351 million. (We used the cost of electricity from a
combined-cycle combustion turbine generator as our benchmark for the
estimated long-term value of power because it is generally the lowest
cost alternative to most hydropower generation.)[Footnote 13] On the
other hand, if hydropower generation in 1999 had been about 10 percent
lower, at about the average level of generation over the past
two decades in California, net benefits would have been about
$218 million. (We used this two-decade average as our benchmark for the
quantity of electricity.) Table 3 shows the results of our sensitivity
analyses in relationship to the results of our 1999 analysis.
Table 3: Results of Our Sensitivity Analyses of Each of the 24 Projects
in Our Sample--1999, 1999 with a Change in Price, and 1999 with a
Change in Quantity:
Dollars in thousands.
Hells Canyon; 1999 value
of federal lands: $145,857; 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: $176,837; 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: $121,831.
Boundary; 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 67,362; 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 82,356; 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: 55,733.
Priest Rapids; 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 24,129; 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 28,554; 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: 20,697.
Skagit River; 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 15,290; 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 26,123; 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: 6,888.
Bath County; 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 10,228; 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 10,228; 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: 3,029.
Big Creek 1 & 2; 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 6,184; 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 9,744; 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: 3,423.
Bliss; 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 3,399; 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 4,764; 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: 2,341.
Pit River; 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 2,535; 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 4,689; 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: 865.
Rocky Reach; 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 1,819; 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 2,182; 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: 1,538.
North Fork; 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 832; 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 1,291; 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: 477.
Rock Island; 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 596; 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 752; 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: 476.
Noxon Rapids; 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 410; 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 874; 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: 50.
Thompson Falls; 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 349; 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 630; 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: 131.
Kerr; 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 339; 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 447; 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: 254.
Swift; 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: 318; 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 586; 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: 111.
Coosa River; 1999 value
of federal lands: ($34); 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: ($40); 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: ($46); 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: [Empty].
Upper North Fork Feather River; 1999 value
of federal lands: (517); 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: (263); 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: (713); 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: [Empty].
Kerckhoff 1 & 2; 1999 value
of federal lands: (4,515); 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: (3,087); 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: (5,622); 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: [Empty].
North Umpqua; 1999 value
of federal lands: (4,731); 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 899; 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: (9,098); 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: [Empty].
Feather River; 1999 value
of federal lands: (6,132); 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: (3,558); 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: (8,128); 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: [Empty].
Don Pedro; 1999 value
of federal lands: (6,587); 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: (5,316); 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: (7,573); 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: [Empty].
Haas-Kings River; 1999 value
of federal lands: (22,205); 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: (20,154); 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: (23,796); 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: [Empty].
California Aqueduct; 1999 value
of federal lands: (22,210); 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: (20,602); 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: (23,457); 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: [Empty].
Upper American River; 1999 value
of federal lands: (34,344); 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: (27,659); 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: (39,529); 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: [Empty].
Total of positive values; 1999 value
of federal lands: 1999 value
of federal lands: $279,648; 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--
price sensitivity: $350,956; 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: 1999 value
of federal lands--quantity sensitivity: $217,844.
Source: GAO.
Note: All data are in 2002 dollars. Details on how we conducted our
sensitivity analyses of 1999 data are included in app. I. Also, as
previously discussed, the totals in this table do not include projects
with negative values.
[End of table]
Estimated Fair Market Value of Federal Lands in 2003:
We developed an estimate for 2003 by (1) using our benchmark
estimate of the value of power, (2) using recent averages for the
quantity of power produced, (3) using recent averages for operating
costs, and (4) developing an estimate of capital costs for 2003. This
estimate is about $386 million, and it reflects what the value for the
use of federal lands would be using more typical values for the price
and quantity of the power produced. However, this estimate is subject
to the uncertainties that exist in electricity markets, including
weather, changes in electricity demand or supply, the costs of
alternative fuels such as natural gas, and future regulatory
constraints, among other factors. Table 4 shows the results of this
analysis and FERC's annual charges for 2002. Overall, the table shows
that FERC's annual charges for the use of federal lands are
significantly below the fair market value of these lands.
Table 4: The Estimated Annual Value for the Use of Federal Lands for
Each of the 24 Projects in Our Sample for 2003, and FERC Annual Charges
for 2002:
Dollars in thousands.
Project name:
Hells Canyon;
2003 value
of federal lands: 2003 value
of federal lands: $194,221; 2002 FERC
annual charges: $371.
Boundary; 2003 value
of federal lands: 2003 value
of federal lands: 85,120; 2002 FERC
annual charges: 34.
Priest Rapids; 2003 value
of federal lands: 2003 value
of federal lands: 28,206; 2002 FERC
annual charges: 49.
Big Creek 1 & 2; 2003 value
of federal lands: 2003 value
of federal lands: 20,730; 2002 FERC
annual charges: 154.
Skagit River; 2003 value
of federal lands: 2003 value
of federal lands: 20,497; 2002 FERC
annual charges: 917.
Bath County; 2003 value
of federal lands: 2003 value
of federal lands: 12,067; 2002 FERC
annual charges: 48.
Bliss; 2003 value
of federal lands: 2003 value
of federal lands: 5,733; 2002 FERC
annual charges: 16.
Pit River; 2003 value
of federal lands: 2003 value
of federal lands: 5,064; 2002 FERC
annual charges: 49.
Kerckhoff 1 & 2; 2003 value
of federal lands: 2003 value
of federal lands: 3,973; 2002 FERC
annual charges: 25.
North Umpqua; 2003 value
of federal lands: 2003 value
of federal lands: 2,305; 2002 FERC
annual charges: 108.
Rocky Reach; 2003 value
of federal lands: 2003 value
of federal lands: 2,013; 2002 FERC
annual charges: 3.
Noxon Rapids; 2003 value
of federal lands: 2003 value
of federal lands: 1,382; 2002 FERC
annual charges: 22.
North Fork; 2003 value
of federal lands: 2003 value
of federal lands: 1,269; 2002 FERC
annual charges: 7.
Rock Island; 2003 value
of federal lands: 2003 value
of federal lands: 732; 2002 FERC
annual charges: 1.
Thompson Falls; 2003 value
of federal lands: 2003 value
of federal lands: 687; 2002 FERC
annual charges: 4.
Swift; 2003 value
of federal lands: 2003 value
of federal lands: 572; 2002 FERC
annual charges: 19.
Kerr; 2003 value
of federal lands: 2003 value
of federal lands: 556; 2002 FERC
annual charges: 2.
Feather River; 2003 value
of federal lands: 2003 value
of federal lands: 229; 2002 FERC
annual charges: 9.
Upper North Fork Feather River; 2003 value
of federal lands: 2003 value
of federal lands: 207; 2002 FERC
annual charges: 85.
Coosa River; 2003 value
of federal lands: 2003 value
of federal lands: 2; 2002 FERC
annual charges: 7.
Don Pedro; 2003 value
of federal lands: ($5,635); 2003
value
of federal lands: 2002 FERC
annual charges: 249.
Haas-Kings River; 2003 value
of federal lands: (6,815); 2003 value
of federal lands: 2002 FERC
annual charges: 202.
Upper American River; 2003 value
of federal lands: (15,175); 2003
value
of federal lands: 2002 FERC
annual charges: 286.
California Aqueduct; 2003 value
of federal lands: (20,029); 2003
value
of federal lands: 2002 FERC
annual charges: 17.
Total of positive values; 2003 value
of federal lands: 2003 value
of federal lands: $385,563; 2002 FERC
annual charges: $2,685.
Source: GAO.
Note: All data are in 2002 dollars. Also, as previously discussed, the
totals in this table do not include projects with negative values.
[End of table]
Most of the Lands Used by Individual Projects in Our Sample Are Worth
Significantly More Than FERC Currently Charges:
Our analyses for 1998, 1999, 2000, and 2003 found that the lands in our
sample are worth significantly more than FERC currently charges for
most years and for most projects. However, for each project, the value
of the federal land can change dramatically with a significant change
in supply and demand for electricity. For example, as discussed
earlier, in some years when electricity prices are low, the value of
power is so low that a project produces a negative net benefit.
In general, for the years we examined, we found the following
differences among the projects in our sample:
* In 1998, prices were so low that the value of the power produced by
15 of the 24 projects was less than the cost to produce the power--
including a 7.2 percent rate of return--resulting in a negative net
benefit. The lands associated with the remaining nine projects were
estimated to be worth $157 million.
* In 1999, electricity prices were somewhat higher than in 1998 but
still low from a historical perspective. As a result, the lands
associated with 15 of the 24 projects were estimated to be worth
$280 million, while the remaining 9 projects had negative net benefits.
* In 2000, the electricity crisis in the West drove prices to
extraordinarily high levels. As a result, 22 projects had lands
estimated to be worth about $1.7 billion, and only two projects in our
sample had a negative net benefit.
* For 2003, we estimated that the federal lands in 19 of the
24 projects would be worth about $386 million and that the federal
lands within the remaining projects would be worth little, if anything,
for hydropower uses above what they currently pay in
annual charges.[Footnote 14]
For 2003, of the 19 projects whose federal lands are worth
significantly more than current annual charges suggest, five projects
are on federal lands worth exceptionally more. We estimate the lands in
these five projects to be worth about $349 million annually, or about
90 percent of the value of all of the lands in our sample of
24 projects. FERC currently collects annual charges totaling about
$1.5 million from these five projects, but our analysis estimates that
the land in each project is worth from $20 million to $193 million more
than what FERC currently charges. These five projects are:
* Hells Canyon (Idaho Power) in Idaho,
* Boundary (City of Seattle),
* Skagit River (City of Seattle),
* Priest Rapids (Grant County Public Utility District) in Washington
State, and:
* Big Creek 1 & 2 (Southern California Edison) in California.
These projects are among those that (1) generated the largest volume of
electricity, (2) had the lowest level of capital costs, and/or (3) used
the highest percentage of federal lands. However, three of these
projects are owned by municipalities (Boundary, Skagit River, and
Priest Rapids). Section 10(e) of the Federal Power Act exempts
licensees for state and municipal power projects from paying annual
charges to the extent project power is sold to the public without
profit or for state or municipal purposes. Each of these three projects
received a partial exemption in the recent past that reduced their
annual charges by about 9 percent for Boundary and Skagit River, and
about 35 percent for Priest Rapids.
Limitations of Our Analysis:
Our estimates of the fair market value of federal lands used to produce
hydropower are subject to a number of uncertainties that can affect
the price or quantity of hydropower produced. Changes in the weather,
regulatory constraints, or the cost of fuels can dramatically affect
electricity markets. Weather and rainfall patterns can affect the
supply, price, and demand for electricity. For example, a hot, dry
spring season will increase the demand for power and, at the same time,
reduce the availability of hydropower. In addition, future regulatory
actions established through the relicensing of hydropower projects
could, among other things, limit the future quantity--or increase the
cost--of hydropower produced at some projects. Furthermore, electricity
markets are influenced by the cost of fuels, such as coal and natural
gas, used to generate electricity at non-hydropower-generating plants.
These uncertainties are best illustrated by the dramatic changes in the
fair market value of the lands between 1998 and 2000. Finally, our
analysis is also limited by the lack of available historical data on
wholesale electricity prices because active markets have been in
operation for only a few years. We cannot quantify the impact of these
uncertainties on our overall estimates. However, it remains clear that,
no matter how volatile the market, the federal lands used by our sample
of projects to produce hydropower are worth significantly more than
FERC's current annual charges indicate.
Effect of Higher Annual Charges on Consumers and Project Owners Will
Depend on FERC's Implementation and the Regulatory Environment:
If FERC decides to collect annual charges that more closely reflect the
fair market value for the use of the land, the effects on consumers and
project owners will depend on (1) how FERC chooses to implement these
higher charges and (2) whether the electricity industry in the state
where the project is located has been restructured.
Impacts Will Depend on FERC's Implementation:
When considering the actions it could take to revise its annual charge
system, FERC must balance any increases in charges with the Federal
Power Act's requirement to seek to avoid unreasonable increases in
consumer rates, and the act's goal of encouraging the development of
hydropower. FERC may therefore decide to collect only a portion of the
fair market value of the land as an annual charge. Clearly, if FERC
decides to continue charging a small portion of the fair market value
of federal lands, then the impact on hydropower project owners and
consumers will be minimal. However, if FERC decides to collect a
much higher percentage of the fair market value of federal lands as an
annual charge, then project owners and/or consumers could be
significantly affected.
If FERC increases annual charges to 100 percent of the fair market
value for the use of the land, then the electricity rates of some
utilities could experience significant increases. These utilities would
include those that rely heavily on FERC-licensed hydropower, such as
those in states like:
Idaho, Oregon, and Washington. For example, one Idaho Power project in
our sample--Hell's Canyon--uses federal lands that we estimated would
be worth about $146 million in 1999. If 100 percent of the estimated
value of these federal lands became FERC's basis for its annual
charges, then the total cost to operate all of Idaho Power would
increase by about 25 percent, from about $580 million to about
$726 million.[Footnote 15] Because Idaho Power operates under state
regulation, this cost increase for the Hell's Canyon project would
probably be passed on to Idaho Power's customers through higher rates.
We did not include in our sample all of the hydropower projects that
Idaho Power owns and that use federal lands. Therefore, Idaho Power's
costs could increase even more than the increase for the Hell's Canyon
project if FERC decides to increase annual charges to 100 percent of
fair market value for these other projects. However, the Hell's Canyon
hydropower project alone accounts for about 70 percent of all of Idaho
Power's hydropower generating capacity. Consequently, the additional
costs for the other projects are not likely to be as sizable.
Large increases in electricity rates can, in the short term, harm the
economies of the areas the utility serves. Consumers would pay not only
more for their household electricity, but they would also tend to pay
more for other goods and services, as local businesses pass on
increased electricity costs to consumers. In addition, according to
officials from the Idaho Public Utility Commission, increases in
electricity rates of 20 percent or more could reduce or eliminate the
incentive for businesses to relocate to or remain in Idaho and would
therefore affect the unemployment rate.
Such economic impacts are likely to be less pronounced in states where
utilities do not depend as much on FERC-licensed hydropower for a
significant percentage of their generation. Also, impacts will likely
be less in the case of hydropower projects that use a
smaller percentage of federal land. For example, the Chelan County
Public Utility District (PUD) in Washington State pays FERC about
$3,200 in annual charges for its use of federal lands for its Rocky
Reach and Rock Island hydropower projects. These lands account for
about 1 percent of the acreage in each of the projects. We estimated
that these lands could be worth about $2.7 million for 2003. While this
value could result in a large increase in charges, it is only about
2 percent of our total annual estimated cost--about $150 million in
2003--to operate these two projects (including capital costs). Thus,
this increase is not likely to significantly affect the project owner
or its customers.
FERC has options to mitigate the effects on consumers of annual charges
that better reflect the fair market value of the federal lands:
* FERC could collect only a portion of the fair market value of the
land as annual charges.
* FERC could phase in the charges over several years to allow
project operators and consumers to better prepare for and adjust to the
higher rates.
* FERC could also delay implementing any higher annual charges until
electricity markets become more competitive through restructuring. In
restructured markets, to remain competitive, project owners may not be
able to pass on higher annual charges to consumers.[Footnote 16]
However, FERC would need to prepare to implement higher charges while
states are moving toward restructuring their electricity markets. If
FERC is not prepared to act, as discussed below, its opportunities to
increase annual charges at a later date would be limited.
Effect of Higher Costs Will Depend on Market Environment:
The regulatory environment largely determines whether consumers or
project owners pay increased charges for the fair market value of
federal lands used for hydropower. Some of the states that could be
affected by increases in annual charges currently have electricity
industries that are highly regulated--that is, the price to consumers
is based on the cost of production. For example, consumers in Idaho and
Washington State--which now regulate their utilities--would see the
greatest impact because some of their electric utility companies rely
heavily on FERC-licensed hydropower projects for their electricity.
Customers who use these utilities have enjoyed some of the lowest
electricity rates in the country.
In a regulated electricity market, increases in annual charges are most
likely going to be passed on to consumers. However, in a restructured
environment, where electricity rates are based on wholesale market
prices, increased annual charges are much more likely to affect the
profitability of the electric utility and its shareholders than
consumers. Specifically, in a restructured environment with
competition, the utility may not be able to pass on increases in annual
charges and still keep its customers. For this reason, consumers would
less likely be affected. Among the states most likely to be affected by
any significant changes in annual charges, Montana has already made the
transition to market-based pricing of electricity. As a result, in
Montana, the owners of hydropower projects--rather than the customers
of these projects--are likely to pay most of any increase in
annual charges.
FERC's Future Ability to Increase Annual Charges Could Be Limited by
Electricity Market Restructuring:
If FERC decides not to act to collect annual charges that better
reflect the fair market value for the use of federal lands by
hydropower projects until after restructuring occurs, it may limit its
opportunity to increase charges, thereby putting the taxpayers at risk
of losing a potential future stream of revenue. Specifically, FERC's
ability to raise annual charges may be limited after states restructure
the generation segment of their electricity market because new
purchasers of existing hydropower projects on federal land will likely
have paid a price that included the capitalized value of the land.
Some states have moved toward restructuring the generation segment of
their electricity markets. This shift changes the way that the benefits
associated with hydropower are distributed between the ratepayers and
the project owners. In a regulated environment, where rates are based
on the cost of service, ratepayers receive the benefits in the form of
low electricity rates. These rates are associated with the low cost of
hydropower production, including the low annual charges assessed to
those who use federal lands to produce power. However, in restructuring
this industry to create more competition, some states have allowed or
required utilities to sell their power plants, including hydropower
plants that are located partially or entirely on federal land. The sale
price for these
projects may include the net benefits that are attributable to the
contribution the federal lands make to the production of power. When
these projects are sold, either the state and/or the seller have
captured these net benefits.[Footnote 17] The state and/or the seller
are able to capture these net benefits because FERC had not set annual
charges at a level that better reflects the fair market value of the
federal land. If FERC had done so, the project's price would have been
reduced to reflect the higher operating costs associated with annual
charges that more closely reflect fair market value. Once these
projects are sold, the federal government may be reluctant to raise
annual charges because the new owner probably paid a price that
included the capitalized value of the federal land. Any further cost
increases, such as higher annual charges, could make power production
costs exceed the current market price of electricity. As a result, the
new project operator would likely either operate at a loss or lose its
customers to competition. In such situations, FERC may be reluctant to
raise annual charges to better represent the fair market value of the
federal land.
Some states, including Maine, Montana, and New York, have already
restructured the generation segment of their electricity industries in
ways that resulted in the utilities' selling off their hydropower
projects. In these states, both the state and/or the seller captured
the net benefits resulting from the sale of the projects. In Maine and
Montana, the projects were auctioned, and the winning bids were well
above the amounts that the regulators deemed sufficient to reimburse
the selling utility for the value of its fixed assets, including the
land owned by the utility. However, in Montana, where some of the
hydropower projects' land is federally owned, the sale price was likely
higher than it would have been if annual charges had more closely
reflected fair market value. In fact, the new owners of these assets
told us that their bid would have been lower if they had expected
higher annual charges for the federal land. If FERC had implemented
higher charges, more revenues would have accrued to the federal
government and less to the state of Montana.
Figure 3 graphically depicts how the sale of a hydropower project--sold
as part of a state's effort to restructure its electricity market--
causes the capitalized value of the land's net benefit to become a
component of the project's selling price and thus the buyer's capital
costs. However, this higher selling price would be at the expense of
taxpayers who are at risk of losing a potential future stream of
revenue. As FERC has observed in connection with annual charges
assessed for the use of government dams, an "overly low annual charge
payment—ultimately places higher costs on other consumer members of the
public who must make up the difference through their taxes."[Footnote
18]
Figure 3: Illustration of the Cost to Produce Hydropower Before and
After a Sale That Occurs as Part of Restructuring:
[See PDF for image]
[End of figure]
Conclusion:
Under the Federal Power Act, FERC is required to collect reasonable
annual charges to compensate the federal government for the use of its
lands. FERC must balance the amount of these annual charges with the
authorizing act's requirement to seek to avoid unreasonable increases
in consumer rates and the act's goal of encouraging the development of
hydropower. However, by tying the annual charges to an out-of-date
rights-of-way fee system, FERC is collecting less than 2 percent of our
estimate of the fair market value for the use of federal lands by our
sample of hydropower projects. FERC has not conducted any research and
analysis to determine whether its current annual charges are
reasonable. Thus, FERC has no assurance that its current system strikes
a balance between those who benefit from the federal lands--consumers
and hydropower project owners--and the taxpayers who own the lands.
Even if FERC could ensure that it was assessing reasonable annual
charges, administrative problems with the current system--self-
reported data and conflicting information in the databases--would
hamper FERC's ability to collect all moneys due.
In addition, as states restructure their electricity markets, inaction
on the part of FERC to reassess what constitutes a reasonable annual
charge could limit the agency's ability to increase charges in the
future as states distribute the net benefits of hydropower projects
that are sold during the restructuring process. In the end, if FERC
does not act, taxpayers who do not benefit from low hydropower
electricity rates may lose the opportunity to benefit from a potential
future stream of revenue.
Recommendations for Executive Action:
We recommend that FERC reassess its system of annual land use charges
in light of the (1) information we are providing concerning the
estimated value of the contribution that federal lands make to the
production of hydropower, (2) trend toward the restructuring of the
nation's electricity markets, and (3) flaws in its present system.
Specifically, FERC should develop new strategies and options for
assessing annual charges that are proportionate with the benefits
conveyed to hydropower licensees. In conducting this reassessment, FERC
should (1) determine methods for assessing or estimating the fair
market value of federal lands used for hydropower purposes and
(2) determine methods for assessing annual charges, taking into account
the federal land's fair market value as well as the competing goals of
encouraging hydropower development and avoiding unreasonable increases
in electricity rates to consumers.
In the interim, while FERC is developing this strategy, we further
recommend that FERC improve its internal control systems in the
following ways:
* improve the management of its current system for assessing annual
charges through periodically verifying self-reported data on the amount
of federal lands licensed hydropower projects use, and:
* resolve discrepancies among its multiple billing and land databases
in order to ensure that each project is properly billed for the annual
land use charges it owes the federal government.
Agency and Industry Comments:
We provided FERC, the Department of the Interior, the Forest Service,
and the National Hydropower Association--a hydropower industry group--
with a draft of this report for their review and comment. The Forest
Service declined to comment on the report. Interior agreed with the
report and provided some technical clarifications and observations.
(See app. V for Interior's comments and our response.):
FERC generally agreed with our findings and recommendations on the
conflicting information in the databases it uses to manage its annual
charge system, but it generally disagreed with our assessment of the
value of federal lands used by hydropower projects. FERC questioned the
validity of our analysis of the value of federal lands because our
analysis resulted in values that were significantly higher than current
annual charges. However, it is difficult for FERC to make meaningful
comparisons on the basis of current annual charges because, as we
discuss, FERC's annual charge system is based on a fee schedule that
was not designed for hydropower uses and moreover does not accurately
assess fair market value for its originally intended purpose.
Furthermore, FERC has not performed any analysis of the value of these
federal lands in over 15 years, and therefore cannot ensure that the
charges it collects meet the objectives of its annual charge program.
FERC also raised concerns about (1) using a net benefits approach as a
mechanism to collect annual charges and (2) linking annual charges to
electricity markets, which have recently been volatile. Concerning our
use of the net benefits approach, our report recommends that FERC
reassess its current annual charge system and look for ways to better
account for the value of federal lands. We used the net benefits
approach as a method to illustrate the contributions that these lands
make to the production of hydropower. We do not specifically recommend
that FERC deploy our approach to value the land as a mechanism for
determining annual charges. Concerning the linking of annual charges to
electricity markets, our report recognizes the volatility that has
recently occurred in these markets. If FERC decides to reassess and
revise its annual charge system, it does not have to use an annual
charge system that fluctuates with electricity markets. FERC can decide
to use a system based on long-term expectations, which would tend to
mitigate short-term volatility. In the past, FERC has approved annual
charges for tribal lands that (1) were based on a long-term analysis of
the value for the use of the land and (2) were a fixed amount so that
licensees could plan and budget for them. (See app III. for FERC's
comments and our response.):
NHA disagreed with the report. It raised several concerns about having
FERC use a net benefits approach to levy annual charges. However, we
do not specifically recommend this use. Instead, we used the net
benefits approach as a tool to value the federal lands used by a sample
of FERC-licensed hydropower projects. In so doing, we found that FERC
is collecting only a very small percentage of the federal lands' value
in its current annual charge system, and recommend that FERC reassess
its current annual charge system without recommending a specific
approach. NHA also commented that increased annual charges will
increase electricity rates to consumers, which could adversely affect
the economy of some states that benefit from low-priced hydropower. We
recognized this possibility. As our report discusses, the impacts from
increased annual charges largely depend on (1) how much of the land's
value FERC decides to collect as an annual charge and how it implements
any higher charges and (2) whether the affected electricity market is
still fully regulated or has been restructured.
NHA also commented that potential annual charges for the use of federal
land should be reduced to recognize the public benefits provided by
hydropower projects, such as recreation, flood control, irrigation, and
fish and wildlife enhancement. However, FERC has twice rejected this
argument, saying, in essence, that under the Federal Power Act, public
benefits are provided as a condition of receiving the license and that
the licensee deserves no compensation for merely complying with the
law. (See app. IV for NHA's comments and our response.):
Scope and Methodology:
To determine FERC's current system for assessing annual charges, we
reviewed relevant laws, regulations, and FERC rulings. In addition, we
interviewed officials from FERC, federal land management agencies, and
industry associations concerning the history and application of the
current annual charge system. We also reviewed pertinent documents from
these sources, as well as past reports from GAO and the Department of
Energy's Office of the Inspector General. To assess FERC's management
of its current system we obtained records from multiple FERC databases
for various years. These records included information on billing, the
type of federal land associated with each hydropower project (e.g.,
Forest Service, BLM), and the number of federal acres associated with
each project in our sample. We assessed the reliability of FERC's data
by analyzing and crosschecking the information that was provided. In
addition, we interviewed FERC officials and requested a variety of
documents in an attempt to clarify discrepancies found in the data.
To estimate the values of the federal lands that utility companies use
to generate hydropower, we performed a net benefits analysis using
project-specific data for a sample of 24 hydropower projects that use
federal lands. We developed this sample by obtaining information on the
amount of hydropower generated by each FERC-licensed project that
uses federal lands. We then determined that the 56 projects with the
greatest generation produced about 90 percent of the power generated
by FERC-licensed projects on federal lands. From these 56 projects, we
selected 24 using a stratified random sampling method. The projects
were grouped into four strata based on the size of the project as
determined by the amount of generation produced. The first stratum
included the largest projects, the second stratum had the next largest
group, and so forth. We weighted the sample toward the largest
generators by sampling 9 of the 10 projects in the first stratum. We
grouped the remaining projects among the other three strata according
to size. Five projects were randomly selected from each of the other
strata. (For greater detail on our methodology see app. I.) We
discussed the merits and limitations of this approach with officials
from FERC, hydropower project owners, and several industry
associations, including the National Hydropower Association and the
Western Utilities Group.
To determine what effect an increase in annual charges might have on
utilities and their customers, we met with utility representatives with
projects in our sample to share the results of our analysis and discuss
the implications of having FERC increase annual charges to the values
that our analysis suggests. In addition, we spoke with state regulators
in California, Idaho and Montana; FERC officials; hydropower project
owners; and industry associations to obtain their views concerning
potential impacts associated with an increase in annual charges.
Finally, we met with representatives from a taxpayer advocacy group to
discuss any implications of FERC's inaction on general taxpayers who do
not receive any benefits associated with hydropower projects on
federal lands.
To identify the potential implications of FERC's not addressing its
current annual charge system in a timely manner, we relied on generally
accepted economic principles of regulated and restructured markets to
identify the possible consequences of FERC's inaction. In addition, we
looked at available data for a recent sale of hydropower projects in
Montana that included federal lands. On the basis of generally accepted
economic principles and the data from that sale, we developed a
probable scenario concerning the distribution of the net benefits when
a hydropower project is sold as part of the restructuring of a state's
electricity market.
We conducted our work from August 2000 through February 2003 in
accordance with generally accepted government auditing standards.
We are sending copies of this report to the Commissioners of the
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission; the Secretaries of Agriculture
and of the Interior; the Director, Office of Management and Budget, and
other interested parties. We will also make copies available to others
upon request. In addition, the report will be available at no charge on
the GAO Web site http://www.gao.gov.
If you or your staff have any questions about this report, please call
me on 202-512-3841. Key contributors to this report are listed in
appendix VI.
Barry T. Hill
Director, Natural Resources and Environment:
Signed by Barry T. Hill:
[End of section]
Appendixes:
[End of section]
Appendix I: Estimating the Fair Market Value of Federal Land
Used to Produce Hydropower:
We were asked to estimate the fair market value of federal lands that
are used by hydropower projects that the Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission (FERC) licenses. This appendix describes how we estimated
the fair market value of such lands. The appendix contains four
sections. The first describes our rationale for choosing the net
benefits methodology. The second describes the methodology. The third
describes the decisions that we made in implementing the methodology,
including choices on our sample of dams and the scenarios that we
estimated. Finally, the fourth section describes the data required to
estimate those scenarios.
GAO's Rationale for Choosing the Net Benefits Methodology to Estimate
Fair Market Value:
This section provides a rationale for choosing the net benefits
methodology to estimate fair market value and describes our methodology
in detail. Our net benefits methodology estimates the value of the land
by calculating the difference between the value of the hydropower that
is generated and the full nonland cost of producing it. In the absence
of comparable market sales, the net benefits methodology provides an
alternative for estimating fair market value that is consistent with
economic principles and appraisal practices.
The Principle of the Net Benefits Approach:
Our net benefits approach follows from the long-established economic
principle that allocates to fixed factors of production such as land
the residual value that remains after subtracting the compensation for
all other factors of production at their fair market value. Economic
principles and the real estate appraisal literature advocate market
sales as the most reliable measure of real estate values. In some
cases, there may be no market sales. One such case would be real estate
with special characteristics that limit the usefulness of market sales
for appraising its value. In cases like this, economists and appraisers
advocate alternative approaches to valuing real property. Economists
have used net benefits analysis, and appraisers have used similar
analyses that are generally referred to as "income capitalization
analysis."[Footnote 19] In the case of land values, the real estate
appraisal literature includes a particular variant of income
capitalization analysis that is referred to as the "land residual
technique," with origins and wide support in economics.[Footnote 20]
The land residual technique is particularly similar to our net benefits
methodology.
Our net benefits methodology, like the land residual technique, starts
with the value of the goods that are produced and then subtracts the
costs of all nonland factors of production. The residual net benefits
are the estimated value of the land.
Land that is used for hydropower generation fits the description of
real estate with special characteristics that limit the usefulness of
market sales for appraising its value. Land that is a mile upstream or
downstream from a suitable location may be far less valuable because of
the absence of a special feature, such as a canyon. Hence, land
transactions in the general vicinity of a hydropower project are not
likely to shed light on the value of the project's land.
Electric utility companies have purchased land for use in hydropower
generation, but their purchases were made largely under a regulatory
system that does not reveal the value of the purchased land in the
hydropower generation use. The Federal Power Act gives utilities the
right of eminent domain which allows them to condemn private property
necessary for the construction, maintenance, or operation of the
project; and this ability to condemn property can have a distorting
effect on the economics of utilities' land transactions. Utility
representatives told us that the prices they paid for land acquisitions
for hydropower projects reflected the market value of the land in the
previous use, such as ranching or logging. The value of the land in
such uses is likely to be very different from its value in the intended
use--hydropower generation. In some states, in recent years, lands used
for hydropower generation have also changed hands in cases where
utilities divested their hydropower projects in competitive bidding
auctions. However, in these cases, the prospective buyers typically bid
on packages of electricity generation assets. We had no way of
isolating the value of the land from the overall value of the package
of assets, especially in the absence of a large number of transactions.
Even if the value of land for hydropower generation could be estimated
from such transactions in some cases, it may be of little use for other
cases. The value of land used for hydropower generation in one project
may be quite different from the value of land in another project.
All land that is used to produce hydropower has unique features that
make the land scarce and valuable, and these features provide a
rationale for compensating its owners for its use. The production of
hydropower requires land with certain characteristics, capital
investments on that land, and a staff to manage and operate the
project. The net benefits methodology recognizes that the return on
capital investments is a payment to the owners of the capital,
including compensation for the risk the owners incurred in their
investment. Similarly, the salaries and other operating costs paid to
management and employees at each hydropower facility represent the
market valuation of their contribution to the production of hydropower.
The remaining input required to produce hydropower is land. The fair
market value of that input can be estimated by using the net
benefits methodology.
In adapting this methodology, we estimated the value of the site using
wholesale electricity market prices of the power that the projects in
our sample produced rather than the regulated rates that utilities
actually charged. The values we estimated differ from the contribution
of the hydropower to the actual revenues from the sale of the
hydropower in our sample. Utilities sell power to their ratepayers at
regulated rates that reflect the costs of generation and delivery to
customers. Our analysis is concerned with the generation segment only
of the electric power industry, not the delivery segment (transmission
and distribution). It is possible to estimate the portion of an
electric utility's revenues that corresponds to generation only.
However, given traditional utility regulation, that estimate would
correspond to the portion of our equation that covers the costs of
generation, which include a return on the capital investment. Because
of regulation, the cost of electric power differs from its market
value. Wholesale market prices are a more accurate reflection of the
economic value of power.
In addition, FERC has approved settlements involving Native American
lands occupied by hydropower projects in which the net benefits method
figured prominently in the calculation of the annual charge.
Specifically, the Confederated Tribes of Warm Springs Reservation in
Oregon receives about $11 million annually for their lands in the
Pelton-Round Butte project as the result of a FERC-approved settlement
that was based in part on a net benefits calculation. Moreover, the
Bureau of Indian Affairs has advocated, as standard practice, the use
of the net benefits methodology as a starting point in negotiations
between tribes and owners of hydropower projects.
Outside of the United States, economists in Canada and Norway have
employed methodologies similar to our net benefits methodology in order
to estimate the resource value of hydropower. Economists in these two
countries that rely heavily on hydropower have estimated "hydro-
electric rents" by deducting nonland costs from the value of
hydropower.[Footnote 21] Moreover, the government of Norway uses a net
benefits model for assessing charges on hydropower. The Norwegian
methodology calculates the present value of a hydropower facility's
revenues net of all capital and operations and maintenance costs over
the entire lifetime of the facility. This is another variant of the
land residual or net benefits methodology.[Footnote 22]
Industry Input in Developing Our Approach:
Early in our review, we met with many representatives of electric
utilities, state utility regulators, and other stakeholders to obtain
their views on our methodology for estimating the value of federal land
used for hydropower generation. These stakeholders included
representatives of most of the private and public entities that own the
projects in our sample. Representatives of the owners of projects in
our sample, with few exceptions, generally expressed reservations about
using net benefits as a method for estimating the value of land used
for hydropower generation. Furthermore, even those who said that net
benefits was conceptually a valid method for estimating land values,
still had concerns about using this method as a basis for setting FERC
charges. In addition, industry representative expressed reservations
about estimation difficulties and uncertainties and difficulties in
implementing a system of charges based on the estimates of net
benefits. They also expressed serious concerns about the impacts of
higher FERC charges based on our estimates of net benefits. They cited
potentially serious impacts on ratepayers and, in some cases, local
economies, depending on how FERC would implement a system of higher
charges based on net benefits estimates. On the other hand, state
regulators to whom we described our methodology generally agreed with
its conceptual validity, but some of them also expressed concern about
impacts on ratepayers and on local economies. Industry representatives
and regulators generally agreed that higher charges would have more
impacts on the shareholders of companies in case of restructuring that
allows hydropower to be sold at market rates.
In contrast, from discussions with representatives of several projects
in our sample, it appeared that their preference for FERC's current
method of determining land charges was a result of its simplicity and
relatively low charges.
One of the main substantive arguments that utilities used against our
net benefits approach is that the value of land used for generating
hydropower can be inferred from market transactions in lands in the
general vicinity of the projects. According to this argument, the value
of land in a hydropower project that is surrounded by grazing land, for
example, is likely to be similar to the value of neighboring grazing
plots. However, FERC has observed that the annual charge for federal
lands should be proportionate to the value of the benefit conferred,
and the benefit that the project owner receives from the land is the
ability to operate a hydropower project, not to graze
livestock.[Footnote 23] Federal appeals courts have similarly concluded
that annual charges must be proportional
to the benefit conferred."[Footnote 24] The fallacy of the argument for
valuation based on adjacent lands may be illustrated by the example of
grazing lands. The value of a rancher's land may not change
significantly if it were moved a mile in any direction. Land that is
used for hydropower generation, however, cannot easily be substituted
with other land, even if it is nearby.
In some hydropower project sales in recent years, the right to the use
of the land was bundled with the physical assets. Often, generation
assets sold as packages that included hydropower generation projects as
well as other generation plants that rely on fossil fuels such as coal.
Because of the bundling of the land and physical assets, the sale does
not reveal the market value for these lands. Even if the market value
for hydropower project land could be gathered from such transactions,
little could be said about the value of other lands used to generate
hydropower because of inherent differences in the characteristics of
different lands and in the value of electricity generated in different
regions. As we explain later, wide differences in the topographic
characteristics of project lands greatly affect the value of each
project. Therefore, the value of project land is likely to differ
widely from one project to another.
While we rejected the argument for using adjacent land values to
estimate the value of lands used for hydropower generation, we accepted
a number of specific suggestions that various stakeholders, including
representatives of electric utilities, made regarding our methodology.
For example, we modified our methodology to include utilities'
administrative and general costs and their tax expenses.
A Description of Our Methodology:
We used a net benefits methodology to estimate the fair market value of
federal lands used to generate electricity at a sample of 24
FERC-licensed hydropower projects. For this report, "fair market value"
refers to annual estimates of net benefits rather than a one-time sale
of the permanent right to use the federal land.[Footnote 25] Our
estimate of the net benefits for a given project during a given year is
the difference between the estimates of the market value of power that
the project generates and the full cost of all nonland factors used for
hydropower generation for that year. We defined the full cost of
nonland factors as the sum of the year's (1) annualized capital cost;
(2) operations and maintenance costs; including a share of corporate
overhead; and (3) a share of the owner's direct tax expenses allocated
to the project. All factors of production contribute to the value of
power that a hydropower project generates, and full costs, as we define
them, cover the compensation that all factors--except land--earn on
their contributions. Our net benefit methodology allocates to project
lands the difference between the value of hydropower production at the
project and the full production costs as we defined them. The federal
government's share of net benefits is based on the federal share of the
total land area within the FERC boundaries of a given project.
Our net benefits methodology follows four basic steps:
* To estimate the value of hydropower that a project generates, we
multiplied the quantity of hydropower generated by the wholesale price
for power in its market area. As discussed earlier, our estimates of
the value of power generally differ from the revenues that the project
owners earn from the sale of the hydropower that they generate, because
utilities' revenues are still predominantly based on costs rather than
on market prices.
* For each project, we summed its annualized capital cost; operations
and maintenance costs, including a share of corporate overhead costs;
and a share of the owner's tax expenses allocated to the project.
* We subtracted the sum of costs from the value of hydropower. The
resulting differential represents an estimate of the annualized fair
market value of project lands.
* We multiplied the estimated annualized fair market value of project
lands by the federal government's share of total project lands to
obtain the federal government's share of this estimate.
Figure 4 illustrates how the net benefits methodology estimates the
value of the land by deducting from the value of hydroelectric power
three major cost components: capital costs, operations and maintenance
costs, and taxes.
Figure 4: The Net Benefits Methodology:
[See PDF for image]
[End of figure]
Technical Details of Our Methodology:
While the previous overview of the methodology provides a summary of
the steps taken, we represent the methodology by several equations that
allow it to be implemented, using data on a sample of dams. The
methodology estimates the fair market value of the federal land for a
given project during a given year. The model can be summarized as
follows in equations 1 and 2:
[See PDF for image]
[End of figure]
Project land is all the land within the project boundary, excluding
lands used for transmission rights of way.
On the cost side, we included operations and maintenance costs, a share
of the owner's tax expenses assigned to the project, and annualized
capital cost in equation 3:
[See PDF for image]
[End of figure]
We assumed that the depreciation factor, , stays constant for the
period of analysis, 1998 through 2003. Capital additions, replacement
of major equipment, or major maintenance over a longer period would
result in the annual depreciation factor's changing over time. We chose
this method of annualizing capital costs because it is widely used in
utility industries. A utility is allowed to set electricity rates that
will recover its full estimated costs, including depreciation and a
return on the net value of its capital investment--the value remaining
after accumulated depreciation has been subtracted.[Footnote 26]
[See PDF for image]
[End of figure]
Table 5 illustrates our methodology further with a numeric example for
a hypothetical Project X.
* We start by calculating the value of power--the project's generation
amount multiplied by the wholesale electric power price. In our
example, we multiply 5 billion kilowatt-hours that the plant produces
in 2003 by a price of $0.04/kwh (or $40/megawatt-hour). The result is
$200 million.
* Next we calculate nonland costs of $130 million by adding capital
costs, operations and maintenance costs, and corporate taxes.
* Capital costs consist of (1) an annual depreciation allowance of
$25 million, and return on investment of $75 million (replacement cost
less physical depreciation of $1 billion multiplied by the after-tax,
regulated real rate of return of 7.5 percent; we chose 7.5 percent
instead of 7.22 percent for simplicity for this example);
* taxes are a prorated share of corporate taxes and equal $10 million;
and:
* operations and maintenance costs, including a share of the project
owner's overhead costs, are $20 million.
The sum of costs is $130 million. The net benefit is therefore
$200 million minus $130 million, which is $70 million. For this
hypothetical example, this $70 million is our estimate of the
annualized value of project lands for 2003. To obtain the federal
government's share, we multiply this amount by the federal government's
share of project lands, 10 percent in this hypothetical example, to
obtain $7 million as our estimate of the fair market value of the
federal land for 2003.
Table 5: Numeric Example of Summary Net Benefits Calculations:
Project X: Generation (kwh); Year 2003: 5,000,000,000.
Project X: Price in $/kwh; Year 2003: 0.04.
Project X: Value of power; Year 2003: $200,000,000.
Project X: Replacement cost less physical depreciation; Year 2003:
$1,000,000,000.
Project X: Rate of return on investment; Year 2003: 7.5%.
Project X: Subtotal (return on investment); Year 2003: $75,000,000.
Project X: 1 year's depreciation; Year 2003: $25,000,000.
Project X: Taxes--a prorated share of corporate taxes; Year 2003:
$10,000,000.
Project X: O&M, including a share of corporate overhead; Year 2003:
$20,000,000.
Project X: Total costs; Year 2003: $130,000,000.
Project X: Net benefit; Year 2003: $70,000,000.
Project X: Federal lands' share of project lands; Year 2003: 10%.
Year 2003: Project XYear 2003: $7,000,000.
Source: GAO.
Notes: Hypothetical example.
kwh = kilowatt-hour:
[End of table]
Implementing the Net Benefits Methodology:
This section of the appendix describes the decisions that we made to
implement the net benefits methodology for estimating fair market
value. It includes information on our sample of 24 dams, the six
scenarios that we estimated, and the different types of data that are
required to determine fair market value.
Information on Our Sample of 24 Hydropower Dams:
We selected for analysis a random sample of 24 of the 56 largest
FERC-licensed projects that occupy federal land. Twenty-two of the
24 projects in our sample were in western states, while the 2 others
were in Alabama and Virginia. The 24 projects ranged from about
75 megawatts to 2,100 megawatts of generating capacity and accounted
for about 60 percent
of the generation for all FERC-licensed hydropower projects on federal
land.[Footnote 27] In addition, our sample accounted for about
35 percent of the federal lands used by FERC-licensed projects to
generate hydropower.[Footnote 28] Figure 1 in the report illustrates
the geographic distribution of the projects in our sample.
Some of the projects in our sample are owned by private entities while
others are owned by states, municipal utility districts, or other
public entities. Two of the projects in our sample were built primarily
for transporting water from northern California to various locations,
and one was built with irrigation, flood protection, and hydropower
generation as primary purposes.
The sample of dams includes the wide variety of characteristics that
determine the value and costs of any particular dam. The value of
hydropower generated at each dam and its production costs depend on
many factors, including physical characteristics and how the dam is
used for power generation and other purposes. For example, some dams,
known as "run-of-the-river dams," run almost continuously, while others
store water in impoundments and, as a result, use that water at a later
time to produce more electricity during peak demand periods, when the
electricity is more highly valued. Since the value is determined by the
market price at the time the electricity is produced, the two types of
dams have different values, even if they generate the same amount of
hydropower.[Footnote 29] Our sample also includes dams with widely
varying construction costs that depend on the shape of the land around
the dam and other topographic conditions. Table 6 provides profiles of
the dams in our sample.
Table 6: Profiles of Our Sample of 24 Hydropower Projects:
Dollars in millions.
5; Project name: Kerr; State: Montana; Ownership type[A]: IPP; Capacity
in megawatts: 196.
96; Project name: Kerckhoff 1& 2; State: California; Ownership type[A]:
IOU; Capacity in megawatts: 178.
233; Project name: Pit River; State: California; Ownership type[A]:
IOU; Capacity in megawatts: 368.
553; Project name: Skagit River; State: Washington; Ownership type[A]:
Muni; Capacity in megawatts: 688.
943; Project name: Rock Island; State: Washington; Ownership type[A]:
PUD; Capacity in megawatts: 627.
1869; Project name: Thompson Falls; State: Montana; Ownership type[A]:
IPP; Capacity in megawatts: 90.
1927; Project name: North Umpqua; State: Oregon; Ownership type[A]:
IOU; Capacity in megawatts: 186.
1971; Project name: Hells Canyon; State: Idaho-Oregon; Ownership
type[A]: IOU; Capacity in megawatts: 1,167.
1975; Project name: Bliss; State: Idaho; Ownership type[A]: IOU;
Capacity in megawatts: 75.
1988; Project name: Haas-Kings River; State: California; Ownership
type[A]: IOU; Capacity in megawatts: 189.
2075; Project name: Noxon Rapids; State: Idaho-Montana; Ownership
type[A]: IOU; Capacity in megawatts: 466.
2100; Project name: Feather River; State: California; Ownership
type[A]: State; Capacity in megawatts: 762.
2101; Project name: Upper American River; State: California; Ownership
type[A]: Muni; Capacity in megawatts: 740.
2105; Project name: Upper North Fork Feather River; State: California;
Ownership type[A]: IOU; Capacity in megawatts: 348.
2111; Project name: Swift 1; State: Washington; Ownership type[A]: IOU;
Capacity in megawatts: 240.
2114; Project name: Priest Rapids; State: Washington; Ownership
type[A]: PUD; Capacity in megawatts: 1,856.
2144; Project name: Boundary; State: Washington; Ownership type[A]:
Muni; Capacity in megawatts: 1,060.
2145; Project name: Rocky Reach; State: Washington; Ownership type[A]:
PUD; Capacity in megawatts: 1,280.
2146; Project name: Coosa River; State: Alabama; Ownership type[A]:
IOU; Capacity in megawatts: 688.
2175; Project name: Big Creek 1&2; State: California; Ownership
type[A]: IOU; Capacity in megawatts: 152.
2195; Project name: North Fork River; State: Oregon; Ownership type[A]:
IOU; Capacity in megawatts: 92.
2299; Project name: Don Pedro; State: California; Ownership type[A]:
ID; Capacity in megawatts: 167.
2426; Project name: California Aqueduct; State: California; Ownership
type[A]: State; Capacity in megawatts: 1,679.
2716; Project name: Bath County; State: Virginia; Ownership type[A]:
IOU; Capacity in megawatts: 2,100.
Source: GAO's analysis of data from the Energy Information
Administration (EIA), FERC, and Scientech.
[A] ID = irrigation district; IOU = investor-owned utility; IPP =
independent power producer; muni = municipality; PUD = a public utility
district.
[End of table]
We Estimated the Fair Market Value of Federal Land for Six Scenarios:
We produced estimates of fair market value for each of 3 recent years,
1998 through 2000, and the current year, 2003. We also conducted
sensitivity analysis for 1999 estimates by constructing hypothetical
examples to test the impact of a higher price in one case and lower
hydropower generation by each project in the second case. We chose to
estimate land values for 4 years because factors that determine net
benefits can vary considerably from year to year, depending on
wholesale electricity prices, water availability, and restrictions on
water use, among other things.
In order to estimate the net benefits for 2003, we assumed that the
hydropower produced by our sample of plants would be at the average
quantity generated over 5 recent years, 1995 through 2000, and that the
price of wholesale electricity would be equal to the average cost of
production from a newly built, least-cost alternative generation plant.
Currently, the least-cost alternative is a combined-cycle, dual-fuel,
combustion turbine power plant operating primarily on natural gas. Some
industry analysts consider this average cost a good current indicator
of the average tendency of wholesale prices in the long term. While the
data on prices and production for 1998-2000 provide an estimate of the
value of the federal lands during these years, these estimates depended
on the market conditions that prevailed at the time. In the longer
term, the fair market value for the use of the lands would be limited
by the cost of the least-cost alternative source of electricity, as in
the 2003 calculation, rather than sustained higher prices that may
occur during a given year, such as 2000. Such higher prices would
induce investors to build new generating capacity and thereby drive the
long-run price of electricity to the cost of that alternative.
In order to determine the influence of quantity and price variations
independently of each other, we also conducted a sensitivity analysis
for 1999 by constructing a "lower quantity" case and a "higher price"
case.[Footnote 30] The lower quantity sensitivity case for 1999
included 10 percent less generation than the actual figure for each
project in our sample. We chose this 10 percent reduction to reflect
the fact that annual hydropower generation in California from 1983
through 2001 averaged about 10 percent less than its level in 1999. We
also constructed a higher price scenario for 1999 in which we assumed
that the price was equal to $40 per megawatt-hour, which is about
8 percent higher than the price that we originally used for 1999. We
selected $40 because it represents the long-run marginal cost per
megawatt-hour from a newly built, least-cost alternative source of
power generation. (This assumption is similar to our price assumption
for 2003.):
Data to Implement the Net Benefits Methodology:
To estimate the fair market value of federal land, we needed data on
several key variables. This section describes the price and quantity
data we used to estimate the value of the hydropower produced at each
of the 24 facilities. In addition, this section describes the three key
elements of cost data that we used, including (1) annualized capital
costs, (2) operations and maintenance costs, and (3) taxes.[Footnote
31] Finally, it describes the data we used for determining the federal
share of project lands.
Price and Quantity Data:
We used prices of electric power in wholesale markets to value the
hydropower that our sample of 24 projects generated. Wholesale electric
power markets have developed in response to the restructuring of the
electricity industry across the United States. These market prices
differ in two ways from the regulated rates that electric power
consumers have traditionally paid. First, regulated rates are set
through an administrative process, are intended to reflect the
utility's average cost of production, and include returns on the net
value of capital investments, subject to approval by state regulators.
Wholesale market prices largely reflect market forces on both the
supply and demand sides of the market. Second, regulated rates reflect
the costs of a bundle of services, including generation, transmission,
and distribution. Wholesale electricity prices do not reflect the value
of the delivery service, which is provided separately and is still
subject to traditional cost-based regulation.
We used prices from the California Power Exchange (CAPX) for all
projects in the Western Electricity Coordinating Council (WECC) during
1998 through 2000. These include all projects in our sample except the
Coosa River in Alabama and the Bath County in Virginia. Specifically,
we used an average of the hourly wholesale market prices for all
hydropower projects that sold into CAPX, weighted by each individual
unit's hourly generation. We obtained the confidential hourly
generation data from FERC. We used the resulting annual weighted
average price for the projects in Idaho, Montana, Oregon, and
Washington State, as well as California, because of the integrated
nature of WECC. Large quantities of electric power are traded across
the WECC region during the course of the year, despite occasional
transmission constraints within the region at different times. While
transmission constraints prevent trades across subregions at times,
resulting in different prices for different locations, annual averages
tend to converge because of trading activity when transmission capacity
is sufficient. We consulted with a number of experts on this matter and
they agreed that it is reasonable to use the annual average of hourly
prices in California as a proxy for the annual average price for the
entire WECC region.
The operations of CAPX were relevant to our analysis because CAPX
hourly prices were publicly available prices for directly valuing much
of the hydropower generated by the projects in our sample over the
period of our analysis. CAPX was also important to our analysis because
California is a large and important part of the WECC region, which has
been a fairly well integrated market region for electric power. WECC
comprises 14 western states, the Canadian provinces of Alberta and
British Columbia, and portions of northern Mexico. Twenty-two of the
hydropower projects in our sample are in WECC.
For the Coosa River project in Alabama, we used the simple average of
Southeastern Electric Reliability Council (SERC) hourly prices for
1998-2000.[Footnote 32] We used the simple average because hourly
generation data were not available.
The Bath County Pumped Storage (BCPS) project is a special case because
it is a pumped-storage project.[Footnote 33] It is co-owned by Dominion
Virginia Power and Allegheny Power, and is located within PJM's-Western
Hub (PJM-WH). PJM is the centralized wholesale electricity market for
an area that encompasses Maryland, New Jersey, Pennsylvania, and
portions of Virginia and West Virginia; PJM-WH is one of the zones
within PJM. Dominion Virginia Power, which is co-owner of BCPS with
Allegheny Power, uses PJM-WH prices to value the power that it sells
from BCPS for internal accounting purposes, and the Allegheny Power
System is an active participant in PJM-WH.
Dominion Virginia Power provided us with hourly data on the
hydroelectric power that it sold from its share of BCPS hydropower
generation for 1998 and 1999. We used these hourly generation data and
hourly PJM-WH prices to value all BCPS power sold from BCPS in 1998 and
1999. Specifically, for each of these 2 years, we calculated a price on
the basis of average of all hourly prices from PJM-WH, weighted by
Dominion Virginia Power's sales from this project. These weighted
average values can be thought of as average hourly revenue per
megawatt-hour for the respective years, had all Dominion Virginia
Power's share been sold at PJM-WH prices. Dominion Virginia Power did
not provide hourly generation data for 2000, but we used the 1998 and
1999 hourly generation and price data and the hourly PJM-WH price data
for 2000 to extrapolate a weighted average price for BCPS
for 2000.[Footnote 34]
For 2003, we assumed that prices for all projects except BCPS would be
equal to the cost per megawatt-hour from the least cost, newly-built
alternative source of power generation. In the electricity industry,
this average is also known as the "levelized" cost of the least-cost,
long-run alternative. It includes all cost components, including
capital costs and a return on investment. The reasoning behind this
assumption is that investors will not invest in new power generation
capacity if they cannot reasonably expect future prices that will allow
recovery of all costs, including a risk-adjusted return on their
invested capital. We assumed that
hydropower, on average, should be valued at least as highly as base
load power, so we used levelized cost estimates for base load
plants.[Footnote 35] Specifically, we used Global Insight (formerly
DRI-WEFA Inc.) levelized cost estimates for power that is generated by
a combined-cycle, dual-fuel combustion turbine. Global Insight's
estimates are for different regions of the United States, so we used
the estimates for the western and southeastern states--$42 per
megawatt-hour.[Footnote 36] For the special case of BCPS for 2003, we
used the levelized cost estimate of about $41 per megawatt-hour (in
2002 dollars) but extrapolated a price based on the 1998 and 1999 data.
For all the projects in our sample, we escalated wholesale prices by 7
or 12 percent to reflect the value of ancillary services. Ancillary
services include services related to the provision of electricity other
than simple generation, transmission, or distribution.[Footnote 37] The
provision of "balancing energy supply" is an example of an ancillary
service. This is energy that is not scheduled in advance but is
required to meet energy imbalances in real time to maintain the
reliability of the electric system. Because markets for electricity
ancillary services in the United States are generally not well
developed, we tried to account for their value by escalating the
wholesale market price by a fixed percent. Hydropower projects are
recognized as very important sources of ancillary services. We used a
7 percent price escalation factor for all our sample projects except
for the Bath County project pumped storage project in Virginia (BCPS.)
We chose 7 percent as a conservative number after consulting with a
number of experts and reviewing how other studies accounted for the
value of ancillary services. For BCPS, we used a 12 percent price
escalation factor that the project owner agreed was a reasonable
number. Table 7 provides some detail on the wholesale market prices we
used in our analysis.
Table 7: Prices Used to Value Hydropower for Our Sample of 24 Projects:
Year: 1998; Project by location: California and the Northwest[A]:
Price[C]: $27.40;
Project by location: California and the Northwest[A]: Basis:
Hydro-specific average of hourly prices from CAPX, weighted by hourly
generation[D]; Project by location: : Project by location:
Coosa River, Alabama: Price[C]: $40.01; Project by location: Coosa
River, Alabama: Project by location: Coosa River, Alabama:
Basis: Simple average of hourly prices for the Southeast Reliability
Council region, excluding Florida; Project by location:
Project by location: Bath County Pumped Storage[B]: Price[C]: $36.86;
Project by location: Bath County Pumped Storage[B]: Project by
location: Bath County Pumped Storage[B]: Basis: Average of hourly real-
time prices for PJM-Western Hub, weighted by project hourly generation.
Year: 1999; Project by location: California and the Northwest[A]:
Price[C]: 35.43;
Project by location: California and the Northwest[A]: Basis:
Hydro-specific average of hourly prices from CAPX, weighted by hourly
generation[D]; Project by location: : Project by location:
Coosa River, Alabama: Price[C]: 42.14; Project by location: Coosa
River, Alabama: Project by location: Coosa River, Alabama:
Basis: Simple average of hourly prices for the Southeast Reliability
Council region, excluding Florida; Project by location:
Project by location: Bath County Pumped Storage[B]: Price[C]: 55.16;
Project by location: Bath County Pumped Storage[B]: Project by
location: Bath County Pumped Storage[B]: Basis: Average of hourly real-
time prices for PJM-Western Hub, weighted by project hourly generation.
Year: 2000; Project by location: California and the Northwest[A]:
Price[C]: 124.54;
Project by location: California and the Northwest[A]: Basis:
Hydro-specific average of hourly prices from CAPX, weighted by hourly
generation[D]; Project by location: : Project by location:
Coosa River, Alabama: Price[C]: 34.60; Project by location: Coosa
River, Alabama: Project by location: Coosa River, Alabama:
Basis: Simple average of hourly prices for Southeast Reliability
Council region, excluding Florida; Project by location:
Project by location: Bath County Pumped Storage[B]: Price[C]: 44.34;
Project by location: Bath County Pumped Storage[B]: Project by
location: Bath County Pumped Storage[B]: Basis: Extrapolated from
simple average of hourly PJM-Western Hub prices, adjusted to reflect
peak values.
Year: 2003; Project by location: California and the Northwest[A]:
Price[C]: 41.21;
Project by location: California and the Northwest[A]: Basis:
Levelized cost of electricity from a combined-cycle dual fuel plant for
the Western region; Project by location: : Project by
location: Coosa River, Alabama: Price[C]: 41.21; Project by location:
Coosa River, Alabama: Project by location: Coosa River,
Alabama: Basis: Levelized cost of electricity from a combined-cycle
dual fuel plant for Southeast Reliability Council; Project by location:
Project by location: Bath County Pumped Storage[B]: Price[C]:
64.68; Project by location: Bath County Pumped Storage[B]:
Project by location: Bath County Pumped Storage[B]: Basis: Extrapolated
from levelized cost of electricity from a combined-cycle dual fuel
plant for the Southeast Reliability Council.
Year: 1999 higher price sensitivity; Project by location: California
and the Northwest[A]: Price[C]: 40.00; Project by location: California
and the Northwest[A]: Project by location: California and the
Northwest[A]: Basis: Approximate levelized costs from least-cost base-
load plant; Project by location: : Project by location: Coosa
River, Alabama: Price[C]: 40.00; Project by location: Coosa River,
Alabama: Project by location: Coosa River, Alabama: Basis:
Approximate levelized costs from least-cost base-load plant; Project by
location: Project by location: Bath County Pumped Storage[B]:
Price[C]: 55.16; Project by location: Bath County Pumped Storage[B]:
Project by location: Bath County Pumped Storage[B]: Basis:
Average of hourly real-time prices for PJM-Western Hub, weighted by
project hourly generation.
Year: 1999 lower hydropower generation sensitivity; Project by
location: California and the Northwest[A]: Price[C]: 35.43; Project by
location: California and the Northwest[A]: Project by
location: California and the Northwest[A]: Basis: Hydro-specific
average of hourly prices from CAPX, weighted by hourly generation[D];
Project by location: : Project by location: Coosa River,
Alabama: Price[C]: 42.14; Project by location: Coosa River, Alabama:
Project by location: Coosa River, Alabama: Basis: Simple
average of hourly prices for the Southeast Reliability Council region,
excluding Florida; Project by location: Project by location:
Bath County Pumped Storage[B]: Price[C]: 55.16; Project by location:
Bath County Pumped Storage[B]: Project by location: Bath
County Pumped Storage[B]: Basis: Average of hourly real-time prices for
PJM-Western Hub, weighted by project hourly generation.
Sources: California Power Exchange and California Independent System
Operator, Dominion Generation, the Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission, Global Insight, and PJM Interconnection.
Note: For the Coosa River project, we used data from the Tennessee
Valley Authority, based on Power Markets Weekly.
[A] Projects in the Northwest include Idaho, Montana, Oregon, and
Washington State.
[B] Pumped-storage facilities have high pumping costs that we accounted
for separately.
[C] Prices per megawatt-hour, in 2002 constant dollars. One megawatt-
hour is equal to 1,000 kilowatt-hours. Prices exclude the value of
ancillary services.
[D] CAPX = California Power Exchange.
[End of table]
As we mentioned above, we constructed two sensitivity cases for 1999,
one assuming lower hydropower generation and the other assuming a
higher price. For the lower-generation case, we used the same price as
our 1999 "base case." For the 1999 higher-price case, we assumed a
price of $40 per megawatt-hour for all projects except BCPS. As with
the 2003 prices assumption, we selected this price because it is
approximately equal to the cost of power from the least-cost, new
alternative generation source.
The hydropower generation data for 1998 through 2000 came from several
sources. For the investor-owned utilities, we used data from the
project owners' annual FERC form 1. For publicly owned projects--those
owned by state agencies, municipalities, public utility districts, or
irrigation districts--we used Energy Information Administration (EIA)
form 412, which the utilities are required to submit to EIA. For 2003,
we used for each project the average net generation for 1995-2000. To
compute these averages, we obtained the 1995-2000 data from RDI
databases, a service of Platts Global Energy. Our 5-year average
included a mix of relatively high and low hydropower generation years
in the western U.S.
Capital Cost Data:
We hired Scientech, an expert power plant engineering and consulting
firm, to provide us with capital cost estimates because FERC'S and
EIA's data on capital costs do not account for the effect of inflation
over long periods of time. FERC's and EIA's data forms contain capital
cost figures that consist of original investment costs plus the cost of
additions and less the cost of retirements in current dollar values.
For example, if a turbine is replaced because of its age, the retired
turbine's original cost is subtracted and the cost of the new one is
added. The forms show only the cumulative capital cost figures; they do
not detail retirements and additions and their dates. For example, 1990
capital expenditures may be added to 1940 capital cost expenditures,
with no adjustment for inflation, rendering the figure unusable for our
purposes. Representatives of hydropower project owners told us that
they could not provide us with detailed, project-by-project data on
major retirements and additions and their dates, especially for
projects that date back many decades. The California Public Utility
Commission regulators also said that searching their records for such
data would be extremely difficult, even if complete data existed.
Given these data constraints, we decided to assign to each project
annual capital costs based on the standard formula of compensating
utilities for their costs, and on a current estimate of the project
owners' net capital investments (net of accumulated depreciation). The
standard formula for compensating utilities for their capital costs is
based an annual depreciation factor and the "net book value of their
investments in equation 5:"[Footnote 38]
[See PDF for image]
[End of figure]
Data on the net book value of the projects are not available. Hence, we
decided to rely instead on an expert consultant's estimates of
replacement cost less physical depreciation (RCLPD). RCLPD is an
estimate of the value, in today's dollars, of the owner's net
investment. Because of inflation, RCLPD is likely to be systematically
higher than net book value (B in the above formula,) and it is
therefore higher than the amount that would adequately compensate
project owners for such costs. Since capital costs are a major
component of total costs in our analysis, our reliance on RCLPD
effectively means that our estimates of capital cost are systematically
high, and our estimates of net benefits are conservative.
A team of Scientech engineers and analysts used extensive data sources
and their hydropower engineering expertise to estimate RCLPD for each
of the individual projects in our sample. Scientech started with
estimates of replacement costs, which are the total capital investment
that would be needed today to reproduce a given project on the
unimproved site. Scientech estimated separately for each project in our
sample the costs of (1) reservoirs, dams, and waterways, (2) power
plant structures, (3) power plant equipment, and (4) roads and bridges.
Next, Scientech made assumptions about the useful life span of these
components of hydropower projects in order to estimate physical
depreciation factors for them. Given knowledge of development dates,
and Scientech's own estimates of replacement costs and depreciation
factors, Scientech estimated RCLPD for each project. It also added, for
each project, an estimate of the cost of licensing that these projects
had incurred in the past.
Scientech estimated RCLPD in 2002 dollar values by first estimating
replacement costs (new) for each category and then making assumptions
regarding their useful life span and their age to estimate their
physical depreciation. It also added, for each project, an estimate of
the cost of licensing that these projects had incurred in the past.
Finally, Scientech estimated an annual depreciation factor, D(i), for
each project as a composite of the depreciation factors in each
category.
Moreover, we assumed that all the capital costs of a project are
allocated to the hydropower function. This is certainly not the case
for at least three projects in our sample. The California Aqueduct and
the Feather River projects in California were built primarily to convey
water over hundreds of miles from northern California to various
locations, making their development costs far higher per megawatt of
electric generation capacity than most other projects in our sample.
The Don Pedro project was built with irrigation and flood protection as
major purposes, in addition to electricity. Since we had no reliable
way of allocating the capital costs of these projects among their major
purposes, we allocated all the capital cost to hydropower generation.
However, this potential overstatement of capital costs could lead to an
understatement of the value of these projects.
In order to provide an annual estimate of the return on the value of
capital, we used a real discount rate of 7.22 percent--a weighted
average cost of capital for investor-owned electric utilities, averaged
over the 5 years 1998 through 2002--from Global Insight. We used the
investor-owned utilities' rate for all projects, although public
utilities' cost of borrowing is lower. We used a real, after-tax
discount rate, based on Global Insight's:
financial data for investor-owned electric utilities. This rate is
consistent with guidance from the Office of Management and
Budget.[Footnote 39] We used a real rate because our analyses relies on
costs (including capital costs) and benefits in constant dollar values.
Operations and Maintenance Costs:
For the operations and maintenance data, we relied on data provided by
project owners on their FERC form 1 and EIA form 412. We used project-
specific costs and added an amount that reflected the owners' general
and administrative costs, or overhead costs. To accomplish this, we
used data from FERC form 1 for each of the investor-owned projects in
our sample. We obtained from these forms the overall corporate
(1) electric operations and maintenance expenses and
(2) administrative and general costs. We then calculated
what percentage the corporate wide administrative and general costs
were of the total corporate operations and maintenance costs. We
multiplied this percentage by the project-specific operations and
maintenance costs. The resulting amounts were added to the operations
and maintenance costs for the investor-owned projects. Because we did
not have adequate information on the publicly owned projects in our
sample, we used an annual average percentage, on the basis of data for
the investor-owned utilities, and applied it to the publicly owned
projects in the sample.
BCPS' operations and maintenance costs posed a special challenge. As we
mentioned above, pumped-storage projects pump water up into a reservoir
during off-peak hours, when the electricity prices are relatively low,
and then generate electricity with the stored water during peak-demand
hours.
FERC form 1 did not include the costs of pumping water that a
pumped-storage facility incurs as part of its normal operations.
However, Dominion Energy provided us with hourly data on its use of
electric power for pumping, as well as power generation, for 1998
and 1999. We used the hourly pumping data and PJM-WH prices to estimate
BCPS' pumping costs for those 2 years. We multiplied the hourly amounts
of power it used for pumping by the PJM-WH hourly prices and summed the
products. We also relied on its 1998 and 1999 data to extrapolate this
project's pumping costs for 2000 and 2003.[Footnote 40]
Taxes:
Taxes are paid at the corporate level--not by individual hydropower
projects. However, to fully account for the total costs for each
project, we assigned a portion of the project owners' taxes to their
projects in our sample. To accomplish this, we obtained the total
corporate taxes and total generation in kilowatt-hours from the FERC
form 1. We then divided the taxes by the total generation to obtain a
"tax per kilowatt-hour." We then multiplied this rate by the amount of
generation at a given project for each year to produce each project's
share of the total taxes. This amount was then added to the total costs
for that project. Publicly owned generators of electric power are
exempt from federal income taxes, but many of them pay significant
amounts of taxes and "tax equivalents." We used a similar method, using
data from EIA form 412s, to assign a portion of the tax burden of the
public entity that owned a project in our sample to the individual
project itself. For example, if Utility A paid $10 million in taxes in
1998 and its Project Y generated 10 percent of A's total generation, we
used 10 percent of $10 million, that is, $1 million, as our tax
estimate.
Our estimate for the projects' year 2003 taxes is an average of their
1998 and 1999 taxes, adjusted for inflation. We excluded 2000 from our
tax calculations because it was a very unusual year for utilities'
finances in the western United States, where most of our sample
projects were located.
Data on the Federal Share of Project Lands:
To determine the percentage of a project's lands that are federal, we
obtained the amount of federal acreage associated with each project
from FERC documents. Because FERC did not have data on the total
acreage of each project (including federal and nonfederal lands), we
generally obtained the total project acreage from the each of the
owners of projects in our sample. (Two project owners chose not to
share this information with us, so we used estimates the Forest Service
provided--one of the agencies that manages the federal lands on which
these projects are located.) From this information, we determined
the percentage of federal land associated with each project by dividing
the number of federal acres by the number of total project acres. We
did not include transmission line acreage in our analysis because we
were interested only in the primary project acres.
[End of section]
Appendix II: Net Benefits Analysis for Each of the 24 Projects in
Our Sample:
This appendix provides details on our estimates of the net benefit of
federal lands for each project. These details include the value of the
power produced and the costs to produce it. Sources for the data used
in this analysis are discussed in appendix I. For some years, our
analysis estimates that the net benefit for several projects are
negative values. As discussed in our report, a negative net benefit
estimate does not mean that the value of the land is negative or, in
most cases, that the project is losing money. Instead, a negative net
benefit estimate indicates that, for that year, the project operated
below the industry average rate of return on investment (7.22 percent)
that we assigned as part of each project's costs. To show how the rate
of return on investment can vary from year to year, the tables below
provide our estimates of the rate of return on investment for each of
the projects in our sample. (In the following tables, some totals do
not add because of rounding).
Table 8: Bath County, FERC License No. 2716:
Dollars in 2002 dollars.
Generation (kwh); 1998: 3,750,777,000; 1999: 4,161,461,000; 2000:
4,519,820,000; 2003: 4,144,019,333.
Price; 1998: $0.0413; 1999: $0.0618; 2000: $0.0497; 2003: $0.0724.
1998: Value of power: $154,855,911; 1999: Value of power: $257,083,891;
2000: Value of power: $224,478,155; 2003: Value of power: $300,181,342.
RCLPD; 1998: $1,174,300,000; 1999: $1,159,900,000; 2000:
$1,145,500,000; 2003: $1,102,300,000.
Rate of return on investment; 1998: 7.22%; 1999: 7.22%; 2000: 7.22%;
2003: 7.22%.
1998: Subtotal (return on investment): $84,784,460; 1999: Subtotal
(return on investment): $83,744,780; 2000: Subtotal (return on
investment): $82,705,100; 2003: Subtotal (return on investment):
$79,586,060.
1-year's depreciation; 1998: $14,400,000; 1999: $14,400,000; 2000:
$14,400,000; 2003: $14,400,000.
1998: Total capital costs: $99,184,460; 1999: Total capital costs:
$98,144,780; 2000: Total capital costs: $97,105,100; 2003: Total
capital costs: $93,986,060.
Taxes; 1998: $22,996,196; 1999: $25,514,120; 2000: $31,061,285; 2003:
$24,255,158.
Operations and maintenance; 1998: $85,111,699; 1999: $96,897,363;
2000: $100,931,663; 2003: $138,844,651.
1998: Total costs: $207,292,355; 1999: Total costs: $220,556,262; 2000:
Total costs: $229,098,047; 2003: Total costs: $257,085,868.
Net benefit; 1998: ($52,436,444); 1999: $36,527,629; 2000:
($4,619,893); 2003: $43,095,474.
Percentage of project
on federal lands; 1998: 28%; 1999: 28%; 2000: 28%; 2003: 28%.
1998: Net benefit of federal lands: ($14,682,204); 1999: Net benefit of
federal lands: $10,227,736; 2000: Net benefit of federal lands:
($1,293,570); 2003: Net benefit of federal lands: $12,066,733.
Estimated return on investment; 1998: 2.75%; 1999: 10.37%; 2000: 6.82%;
2003: 11.13%.
Sources: Various agencies (data), GAO (analysis).
Notes: Owners: Virginia Dominion Power & Allegheny Power.
FERC annual charges (2002): $48,061.
[End of table]
Table 9: Big Creek 1&2, FERC License No. 2175:
Dollars in 2002 dollars.
Generation (kwh); 1998: 1,016,587,421; 1999: 728,211,389; 2000:
770,657,000; 2003: 943,396,000.
Price; 1998: $0.0293; 1999: $0.0379; 2000: $0.1333; 2003: $0.0441.
1998: Value of power: $29,800,271; 1999: Value of power: $27,607,706;
2000: Value of power: $102,698,124; 2003: Value of power: $41,596,288.
RCLPD; 1998: $61,600,000; 1999: $54,850,000; 2000: $48,100,000; 2003:
$27,850,000.
Rate of return on investment; 1998: 7.22%; 1999: 7.22%; 2000: 7.22%;
2003: 7.22%.
1998: Subtotal (return on investment): $4,447,520; 1999: Subtotal
(return on investment): $3,960,170; 2000: Subtotal (return on
investment): $3,472,820; 2003: Subtotal (return on investment):
$2,010,770.
1-year's depreciation; 1998: $6,750,000; 1999: $6,750,000; 2000:
$6,750,000; 2003: $6,750,000.
1998: Total capital costs: $11,197,520; 1999: Total capital costs:
$10,710,170; 2000: Total capital costs: $10,222,820; 2003: Total
capital costs: $8,760,770.
Taxes; 1998: $8,422,837; 1999: $5,990,369; 2000: ($8,346,210); 2003:
$7,206,603.
Operations and maintenance; 1998: $5,315,070; 1999: $4,722,987; 2000:
$4,518,040; 2003: $4,898,434.
1998: Total costs: $24,935,427; 1999: Total costs: $21,423,526; 2000:
Total costs: $6,394,649; 2003: Total costs: $20,865,807.
Net benefit; 1998: $4,864,844; 1999: $6,184,180; 2000: $96,303,474;
2003: $20,730,481.
Percentage of project on
federal lands; 1998: 100%; 1999: 100%; 2000: 100%; 2003: 100%.
1998: Net benefit of federal lands: $4,864,844; 1999: Net benefit of
federal lands: $6,184,180; 2000: Net benefit of federal lands:
$96,303,474; 2003: Net benefit of federal lands: $20,730,481.
Estimated return on investment; 1998: 15.12%; 1999: 18.49%; 2000:
207.44%; 2003: 81.66%.
Sources: Various agencies (data), GAO (analysis).
Notes: Owner: Southern California Edison.
FERC annual charges (2002): $153,780.
[End of table]
Table 10: Bliss, FERC License No. 1975:
Dollars in 2002 dollars.
Generation (kwh); 1998: 491,650,000; 1999: 465,406,000; 2000:
405,601,000; 2003: 463,943,000.
Price; 1998: $0.0293; 1999: $0.0379; 2000: $0.1333; 2003: $0.0441.
1998: Value of power: $14,412,242; 1999: Value of power: $17,644,316;
2000: Value of power: $54,050,585; 2003: Value of power: $20,456,210.
RCLPD; 1998: $93,720,000; 1999: $91,540,000; 2000: $89,360,000; 2003:
$82,820,000.
Rate of return on investment; 1998: 7.22%; 1999: 7.22%; 2000: 7.22%;
2003: 7.22%.
1998: Subtotal (return on investment): $6,766,584; 1999: Subtotal
(return on investment): $6,609,188; 2000: Subtotal (return on
investment): $6,451,792; 2003: Subtotal (return on investment):
$5,979,604.
1-year's depreciation; 1998: $2,180,000; 1999: $2,180,000; 2000:
$2,180,000; 2003: $2,180,000.
1998: Total capital costs: $8,946,584; 1999: Total capital costs:
$8,789,188; 2000: Total capital costs: $8,631,792; 2003: Total capital
costs: $8,159,604.
Taxes; 1998: $984,341; 1999: $1,591,870; 2000: $1,406,085; 2003:
$1,288,105.
Operations and maintenance; 1998: $1,194,352; 1999: $1,597,704; 2000:
$1,562,505; 2003: $1,454,008.
1998: Total costs: $11,125,278; 1999: Total costs: $11,978,762; 2000:
Total costs: $11,600,382; 2003: Total costs: $10,901,717.
Net benefit; 1998: $3,286,964; 1999: $5,665,555; 2000: $42,450,203;
2003: $9,554,493.
Percentage of project on
federal lands; 1998: 60%; 1999: 60%; 2000: 60%; 2003: 60%.
1998: Net benefit of federal lands: $1,972,178; 1999: Net benefit of
federal lands: $3,399,333; 2000: Net benefit of federal lands:
$25,470,122; 2003: Net benefit of federal lands: $5,732,696.
Estimated return on investment; 1998: 10.73%; 1999: 13.41%; 2000:
54.72%; 2003: 18.76%.
Sources: Various agencies (data), GAO (analysis).
Notes: Owner: Idaho Power.
FERC annual charges (2002): $16,327.
[End of table]
Table 11: Boundary, FERC License No. 2144:
Dollars in 2002 dollars.
Generation (kwh); 1998: 3,827,283,720; 1999: 4,445,309,880; 2000:
3,786,081,000; 2003: 4,353,333,000.
Price; 1998: $0.0293; 1999: $0.0379; 2000: $0.1333; 2003: $0.0441.
1998: Value of power: $112,193,100; 1999: Value of power: $168,529,100;
2000: Value of power: $504,534,981; 2003: Value of power: $191,947,487.
RCLPD; 1998: $438,460,000; 1999: $427,670,000; 2000: $416,880,000;
2003: $384,510,000.
Rate of return on investment; 1998: 7.22%; 1999: 7.22%; 2000: 7.22%;
2003: 7.22%.
1998: Subtotal (return on investment): $31,656,812; 1999: Subtotal
(return on investment): $30,877,774; 2000: Subtotal (return on
investment): $30,098,736; 2003: Subtotal (return on investment):
$27,761,622.
1-year's depreciation; 1998: $10,790,000; 1999: $10,790,000; 2000:
$10,790,000; 2003: $10,790,000.
1998: Total capital costs: $42,446,812; 1999: Total capital costs:
$41,667,774; 2000: Total capital costs: $40,888,736; 2003: Total
capital costs: $38,551,622.
Taxes; 1998: $23,023,259; 1999: $21,573,230; 2000: $25,252,386; 2003:
$22,298,245.
Operations and maintenance; 1998: $8,164,029; 1999: $7,662,020; 2000:
$7,093,877; 2003: $7,735,371.
1998: Total costs: $73,634,100; 1999: Total costs: $70,903,024; 2000:
Total costs: $73,235,000; 2003: Total costs: $68,585,237.
Net benefit; 1998: $38,559,000; 1999: $97,626,076; 2000: $431,299,981;
2003: $123,362,250.
Percentage of project
on federal lands; 1998: 69%; 1999: 69%; 2000: 69%; 2003: 69%.
1998: Net benefit of federal lands: $26,605,710; 1999: Net benefit of
federal lands: $67,361,992; 2000: Net benefit of federal lands:
$297,596,987; 2003: Net benefit of federal lands: $85,119,952.
Estimated return on investment; 1998: 16.01%; 1999: 30.05%; 2000:
110.68%; 2003: 39.30%.
Sources: Various agencies (data), GAO (analysis).
Notes: Owner: City of Seattle.
FERC annual charges (2002): $33,538.
[End of table]
Table 12: California Aqueduct, FERC License No. 2426:
Dollars in 2002 dollars.
Generation (kwh); 1998: 1,665,149,000; 1999: 2,055,889,000; 2000:
1,745,986,000; 2003: 1,953,370,000.
Price; 1998: $0.0293; 1999: $0.0379; 2000: $0.1333; 2003: $0.0441.
1998: Value of power: $48,812,223; 1999: Value of power: $77,942,175;
2000: Value of power: $232,670,937; 2003: Value of power: $86,128,137.
RCLPD; 1998: $2,392,100,000; 1999: $2,365,500,000; 2000:
$2,338,900,000; 2003: $2,259,100,000.
Rate of return on investment; 1998: 7.22%; 1999: 7.22%; 2000: 7.22%;
2003: 7.22%.
1998: Subtotal (return on investment): $172,709,620; 1999: Subtotal
(return on investment): $170,789,100; 2000: Subtotal (return on
investment): $168,868,580; 2003: Subtotal (return on investment):
$163,107,020.
1-year's depreciation; 1998: $26,600,000; 1999: $26,600,000; 2000:
$26,600,000; 2003: $26,600,000.
1998: Total capital costs: $199,309,620; 1999: Total capital costs:
$197,389,100; 2000: Total capital costs: $195,468,580; 2003: Total
capital costs: $189,707,020.
Taxes; 1998: $0; 1999: $0; 2000: $0; 2003: $0.
Operations and maintenance; 1998: $18,410,988; 1999: $19,362,864;
2000: $25,995,071; 2003: $21,599,815.
1998: Total costs: $217,720,608; 1999: Total costs: $216,751,964; 2000:
Total costs: $221,463,651; 2003: Total costs: $211,306,835.
Net benefit; 1998: ($168,908,385); 1999: ($138,809,788); 2000:
$11,207,286; 2003: ($125,178,698).
Percentage of project
on federal lands; 1998: 16%; 1999: 16%; 2000: 16%; 2003: 16%.
1998: Net benefit of federal lands: ($27,025,342); 1999: Net benefit of
federal lands: ($22,209,566); 2000: Net benefit of federal lands:
$1,793,166; 2003: Net benefit of federal lands: ($20,028,592).
Estimated return on investment; 1998: 0.16%; 1999: 1.35%; 2000: 7.70%;
2003: 1.68%.
Sources: Various agencies (data), GAO (analysis).
Notes: Owner: California Department of Water Resources.
FERC annual charges (2002): $17,463.
[End of table]
Table 13: Coosa River, FERC License No. 2146:
Dollars in 2002 dollars.
Generation (kwh); 1998: 2,350,723,000; 1999: 1,631,966,000; 2000:
1,028,390,000; 2003: 2,037,752,000.
Price; 1998: $0.0428; 1999: $0.0451; 2000: $0.0370; 2003: $0.0441.
1998: Value of power: $100,631,464; 1999: Value of power: $73,579,712;
2000: Value of power: $38,074,641; 2003: Value of power: $89,848,715.
RCLPD; 1998: $705,520,000; 1999: $680,040,000; 2000: $654,560,000;
2003: $578,120,000.
Rate of return on investment; 1998: 7.22%; 1999: 7.22%; 2000: 7.22%;
2003: 7.22%.
1998: Subtotal (return on investment): $50,938,544; 1999: Subtotal
(return on investment): $49,098,888; 2000: Subtotal (return on
investment): $47,259,232; 2003: Subtotal (return on investment):
$41,740,264.
1-year's depreciation; 1998: $25,480,000; 1999: $25,480,000; 2000:
$25,480,000; 2003: $25,480,000.
1998: Total capital costs: $76,418,544; 1999: Total capital costs:
$74,578,888; 2000: Total capital costs: $72,739,232; 2003: Total
capital costs: $67,220,264.
Taxes; 1998: $14,869,270; 1999: $10,322,842; 2000: $7,054,801; 2003:
$12,596,056.
Operations and maintenance; 1998: $9,016,934; 1999: $8,538,031; 2000:
$9,007,943; 2003: $8,903,706.
1998: Total costs: $100,304,748; 1999: Total costs: $93,439,762; 2000:
Total costs: $88,801,975; 2003: Total costs: $88,720,026.
Net benefit; 1998: $326,716; 1999: ($19,860,049); 2000: ($50,727,334);
2003: $1,128,688.
Percentage of project
on federal lands; 1998: 0.2%; 1999: 0.2%; 2000: 0.2%; 2003: 0.2%.
1998: Net benefit of federal lands: $555; 1999: Net benefit of federal
lands: ($33,762); 2000: Net benefit of federal lands: ($86,236); 2003:
Net benefit of federal lands: $1,919.
Estimated return on investment; 1998: 7.27%; 1999: 4.30%; 2000: -0.53%;
2003: 7.42%.
Sources: Various agencies (data), GAO (analysis).
Notes: Owner: Alabama Power.
FERC annual charges (2002): $6,933.
[End of table]
Table 14: Don Pedro, FERC License No. 2299:
Dollars in 2002 dollars.
Generation (kwh); 1998: 1,053,287,020; 1999: 702,548,000; 2000:
477,697,000; 2003: 636,108,000.
Price; 1998: $0.0293; 1999: $0.0379; 2000: $0.1333; 2003: $0.0441.
1998: Value of power: $30,876,085; 1999: Value of power: $26,634,765;
2000: Value of power: $63,658,133; 2003: Value of power: $28,047,322.
RCLPD; 1998: $505,640,000; 1999: $499,830,000; 2000: $494,020,000;
2003: $476,590,000.
Rate of return on investment; 1998: 7.22%; 1999: 7.22%; 2000: 7.22%;
2003: 7.22%.
1998: Subtotal (return on investment): $36,507,208; 1999: Subtotal
(return on investment): $36,087,726; 2000: Subtotal (return on
investment): $35,668,244; 2003: Subtotal (return on investment):
$34,409,798.
1-year's depreciation; 1998: $5,810,000; 1999: $5,810,000; 2000:
$5,810,000; 2003: $5,810,000.
1998: Total capital costs: $42,317,208; 1999: Total capital costs:
$41,897,726; 2000: Total capital costs: $41,478,244; 2003: Total
capital costs: $40,219,798.
Taxes; 1998: $0; 1999: $0; 2000: $0; 2003: $0.
Operations and maintenance; 1998: $2,968,359; 1999: $2,539,956; 2000:
$3,516,604; 2003: $3,055,939.
1998: Total costs: $45,285,567; 1999: Total costs: $44,437,682; 2000:
Total costs: $44,994,848; 2003: Total costs: $43,275,737.
Net benefit; 1998: ($14,409,482); 1999: ($17,802,918); 2000:
$18,663,284; 2003: ($15,228,415).
Percentage of project
on federal lands; 1998: 37%; 1999: 37%; 2000: 37%; 2003: 37%.
1998: Net benefit of federal lands: ($5,331,508); 1999: Net benefit of
federal lands: ($6,587,080); 2000: Net benefit of federal lands:
$6,905,415; 2003: Net benefit of federal lands: ($5,634,514).
Estimated return on investment; 1998: 4.37%; 1999: 3.66%; 2000: 11.00%;
2003: 4.02%.
Sources: Various agencies (data), GAO (analysis).
Notes: Owners: Turlock and Modesto Irrigation Districts.
FERC annual charges (2002): $249,313.
[End of table]
Table 15: Feather River, FERC License No. 2100:
Dollars in 2002 dollars.
Generation (kwh); 1998: 3,847,301,000; 1999: 2,925,184,000; 2000:
2,524,105,000; 2003: 3,189,787,000.
Price; 1998: $0.0293; 1999: $0.0379; 2000: $0.1333; 2003: $0.0441.
1998: Value of power: $112,779,887; 1999: Value of power: $110,898,596;
2000: Value of power: $336,363,450; 2003: Value of power: $140,644,329.
RCLPD; 1998: $1,586,540,000; 1999: $1,567,080,000; 2000:
$1,547,620,000; 2003: $1,489,240,000.
Rate of return on investment; 1998: 7.22%; 1999: 7.22%; 2000: 7.22%;
2003: 7.22%.
1998: Subtotal (return on investment): $114,548,188; 1999: Subtotal
(return on investment): $113,143,176; 2000: Subtotal (return on
investment): $111,738,164; 2003: Subtotal (return on investment):
$107,523,128.
1-year's depreciation; 1998: $19,460,000; 1999: $19,460,000; 2000:
$19,460,000; 2003: $19,460,000.
1998: Total capital costs: $134,008,188; 1999: Total capital costs:
$132,603,176; 2000: Total capital costs: $131,198,164; 2003: Total
capital costs: $126,983,128.
Taxes; 1998: $0; 1999: $0; 2000: $0; 2003: $0.
Operations and maintenance; 1998: $12,768,334; 1999: $12,360,892;
2000: $11,570,904; 2003: $12,388,113.
1998: Total costs: $146,776,522; 1999: Total costs: $144,964,068; 2000:
Total costs: $142,769,068; 2003: Total costs: $139,371,241.
Net benefit; 1998: ($33,996,635); 1999: ($34,065,471); 2000:
$193,594,382; 2003: $1,273,088.
Percentage of project
on federal lands; 1998: 18%; 1999: 18%; 2000: 18%; 2003: 18%.
1998: Net benefit of federal lands: ($6,119,394); 1999: Net benefit of
federal lands: ($6,131,785); 2000: Net benefit of federal lands:
$34,846,989; 2003: Net benefit of federal lands: $229,156.
Estimated return on investment; 1998: 5.08%; 1999: 5.05%; 2000: 19.73%;
2003: 7.31%.
Sources: Various agencies (data), GAO (analysis).
Notes: Owner: California Department of Water Resources.
FERC annual charges (2002): $9,158.
[End of table]:
Table 16: Haas-Kings River, FERC License No. 1988:
Dollars in 2002 dollars.
Generation (kwh); 1998: 1,000,289,000; 1999: 493,756,000; 2000:
743,326,000; 2003: 860,409,000.
Price; 1998: $0.0293; 1999: $0.0379; 2000: $0.1333; 2003: $0.0441.
1998: Value of power: $29,322,499; 1999: Value of power: $18,719,112;
2000: Value of power: $99,055,981; 2003: Value of power: $37,937,219.
RCLPD; 1998: $407,080,000; 1999: $400,260,000; 2000: $393,440,000;
2003: $372,980,000.
Rate of return on investment; 1998: 7.22%; 1999: 7.22%; 2000: 7.22%;
2003: 7.22%.
1998: Subtotal (return on investment): $29,391,176; 1999: Subtotal
(return on investment): $28,898,772; 2000: Subtotal (return on
investment): $28,406,368; 2003: Subtotal (return on investment):
$26,929,156.
1-year's depreciation; 1998: $6,820,000; 1999: $6,820,000; 2000:
$6,820,000; 2003: $6,820,000.
1998: Total capital costs: $36,211,176; 1999: Total capital costs:
$35,718,772; 2000: Total capital costs: $35,226,368; 2003: Total
capital costs: $33,749,156.
Taxes; 1998: $12,264,819; 1999: $5,391,264; 2000: ($20,449,656);
2003: $8,828,041.
Operations and maintenance; 1998: $3,207,088; 1999: $3,732,820; 2000:
$3,044,591; 2003: $3,377,873.
1998: Total costs: $51,683,083; 1999: Total costs: $44,842,856; 2000:
Total costs: $17,821,303; 2003: Total costs: $45,955,071.
Net benefit; 1998: ($22,360,584); 1999: ($26,123,744); 2000:
$81,234,679; 2003: ($8,017,852).
Percentage of project
on federal lands; 1998: 85%; 1999: 85%; 2000: 85%; 2003: 85%.
1998: Net benefit of federal lands: ($19,006,496); 1999: Net benefit of
federal lands: ($22,205,182); 2000: Net benefit of federal lands:
$69,049,477; 2003: Net benefit of federal lands: ($6,815,174).
Estimated return on investment; 1998: 1.73%; 1999: 0.69%; 2000: 27.87%;
2003: 5.07%.
Sources: Various agencies (data), GAO (analysis).
Notes: Owner: Pacific Gas and Electric.
FERC annual charges (2002): $202,378.
[End of table]
Table 17: Hells Canyon, FERC License No. 1971:
Dollars in 2002 dollars.
Generation (kwh); 1998: 7,482,604,000; 1999: 7,041,547,000; 2000:
5,768,411,000; 2003: 6,998,260,000.
Price; 1998: $0.0293; 1999: $0.0379; 2000: $0.1333; 2003: $0.0441.
1998: Value of power: $219,345,258; 1999: Value of power: $266,956,772;
2000: Value of power: $768,701,233; 2003: Value of power: $308,567,808.
RCLPD; 1998: $703,460,000; 1999: $679,470,000; 2000: $655,480,000;
2003: $583,510,000.
Rate of return on investment; 1998: 7.22%; 1999: 7.22%; 2000: 7.22%;
2003: 7.22%.
1998: Subtotal (return on investment): $50,789,812; 1999: Subtotal
(return on investment): $49,057,734; 2000: Subtotal (return on
investment): $47,325,656; 2003: Subtotal (return on investment):
$42,129,422.
1-year's depreciation; 1998: $23,990,000; 1999: $23,990,000; 2000:
$23,990,000; 2003: $23,990,000.
1998: Total capital costs: $74,779,812; 1999: Total capital costs:
$73,047,734; 2000: Total capital costs: $71,315,656; 2003: Total
capital costs: $66,119,422.
Taxes; 1998: $14,981,058; 1999: $24,084,830; 2000: $19,997,178; 2003:
$19,532,944.
Operations and maintenance; 1998: $5,877,905; 1999: $7,760,440; 2000:
$7,664,822; 2003: $7,114,735.
1998: Total costs: $95,638,775; 1999: Total costs: $104,893,003; 2000:
Total costs: $98,977,656; 2003: Total costs: $92,767,101.
Net benefit; 1998: $123,706,483; 1999: $162,063,769; 2000:
$669,723,577; 2003: $215,800,707.
Percentage of project
on federal lands; 1998: 90%; 1999: 90%; 2000: 90%; 2003: 90%.
1998: Net benefit of federal lands: $111,335,835; 1999: Net benefit of
federal lands: $145,857,392; 2000: Net benefit of federal lands:
$602,751,219; 2003: Net benefit of federal lands: $194,220,636.
Estimated return on investment; 1998: 24.81%; 1999: 31.07%; 2000:
109.39%; 2003: 44.20%.
Sources: Various agencies (data), GAO (analysis).
Notes: Owner: Idaho Power.
FERC annual charges (2002): $371,075.
[End of table]
Table 18: Kerckhoff 1&2, FERC License No. 96:
Dollars in 2002 dollars.
Generation (kwh); 1998: 811,487,000; 1999: 442,526,000; 2000:
519,900,000; 2003: 685,309,000.
Price; 1998: $0.0293; 1999: $0.0379; 2000: $0.1333; 2003: $0.0441.
1998: Value of power: $23,787,952; 1999: Value of power: $16,776,898;
2000: Value of power: $69,282,125; 2003: Value of power: $30,216,696.
RCLPD; 1998: $132,900,000; 1999: $126,700,000; 2000: $120,500,000;
2003: $101,900,000.
Rate of return on investment; 1998: 7.22%; 1999: 7.22%; 2000: 7.22%;
2003: 7.22%.
1998: Subtotal (return on investment): $9,595,380; 1999: Subtotal
(return on investment): $9,147,740; 2000: Subtotal (return on
investment): $8,700,100; 2003: Subtotal (return on investment):
$7,357,180.
1-year's depreciation; 1998: $6,200,000; 1999: $6,200,000; 2000:
$6,200,000; 2003: $6,200,000.
1998: Total capital costs: $15,795,380; 1999: Total capital costs:
$15,347,740; 2000: Total capital costs: $14,900,100; 2003: Total
capital costs: $13,557,180.
Taxes; 1998: $9,949,865; 1999: $4,831,890; 2000: ($14,302,979); 2003:
$7,390,878.
Operations and maintenance; 1998: $3,150,251; 1999: $3,437,569; 2000:
$3,012,817; 2003: $3,249,366.
1998: Total costs: $28,895,497; 1999: Total costs: $23,617,198; 2000:
Total costs: $3,609,938; 2003: Total costs: $24,197,424.
Net benefit; 1998: ($5,107,544); 1999: ($6,840,301); 2000: $65,672,187;
2003: $6,019,272.
Percentage of project
on federal lands; 1998: 66%; 1999: 66%; 2000: 66%; 2003: 66%.
1998: Net benefit of federal lands: ($3,370,979); 1999: Net benefit of
federal lands: ($4,514,599); 2000: Net benefit of federal lands:
$43,343,643; 2003: Net benefit of federal lands: $3,972,720.
Estimated return on investment; 1998: 3.38%; 1999: 1.82%; 2000: 61.72%;
2003: 13.13%.
Sources: Various agencies (data), GAO (analysis).
Notes: Owner: Pacific Gas and Electric.
FERC annual charges (2002): $25,476.
[End of table]
Table 19: Kerr, FERC License No. 5:
Dollars in 2002 dollars.
Generation (kwh); 1998: 1,013,017,230; 1999: 1,112,198,118; 2000:
1,124,722,000; 2003: 1,164,570,000.
Price; 1998: $0.0293; 1999: $0.0379; 2000: $0.1333; 2003: $0.0441.
1998: Value of power: $29,695,615; 1999: Value of power: $42,165,283;
2000: Value of power: $149,880,996; 2003: Value of power: $51,348,308.
RCLPD; 1998: $162,760,000; 1999: $158,745,000; 2000: $154,730,000;
2003: $142,685,000.
Rate of return on investment; 1998: 7.22%; 1999: 7.22%; 2000: 7.22%;
2003: 7.22%.
1998: Subtotal (return on investment): $11,751,272; 1999: Subtotal
(return on investment): $11,461,389; 2000: Subtotal (return on
investment): $11,171,506; 2003: Subtotal (return on investment):
$10,301,857.
1-year's depreciation; 1998: $4,015,000; 1999: $4,015,000; 2000:
$4,015,000; 2003: $4,015,000.
1998: Total capital costs: $15,766,272; 1999: Total capital costs:
$15,476,389; 2000: Total capital costs: $15,186,506; 2003: Total
capital costs: $14,316,857.
Taxes; 1998: $7,033,669; 1999: $7,740,389; 2000: $4,968,029; 2003:
$7,387,029.
Operations and maintenance; 1998: $1,806,949; 1999: $2,021,255; 2000:
$1,592,134; 2003: $1,824,738.
1998: Total costs: $24,606,889; 1999: Total costs: $25,238,033; 2000:
Total costs: $21,746,669; 2003: Total costs: $23,528,624.
Net benefit; 1998: $5,088,725; 1999: $16,927,250; 2000: $128,134,327;
2003: $27,819,685.
Percentage of project
on federal lands; 1998: 2%; 1999: 2%; 2000: 2%; 2003: 2%.
1998: Net benefit of federal lands: $101,775; 1999: Net benefit of
federal lands: $338,545; 2000: Net benefit of federal lands:
$2,562,687; 2003: Net benefit of federal lands: $556,394.
Estimated return on investment; 1998: 10.35%; 1999: 17.88%; 2000:
90.03%; 2003: 26.72%.
Sources: Various agencies (data), GAO (analysis).
Notes: Owner: PP&L Montana.
FERC annual charges (2002): $1,823.
For this project, operations and maintenance costs were adjusted to
exclude payments made for the use of Native American lands.
[End of table]
Table 20: North Fork, FERC License No. 2195:
Dollars in 2002 dollars.
Generation (kwh); 1998: 507,690,000; 1999: 586,514,000; 2000:
466,426,000; 2003: 535,966,000.
Price; 1998: $0.0293; 1999: $0.0379; 2000: $0.1333; 2003: $0.0441.
1998: Value of power: $14,882,439; 1999: Value of power: $22,235,722;
2000: Value of power: $62,156,154; 2003: Value of power: $23,631,853.
RCLPD; 1998: $100,280,000; 1999: $96,460,000; 2000: $92,640,000;
2003: $81,180,000.
Rate of return on investment; 1998: 7.22%; 1999: 7.22%; 2000: 7.22%;
2003: 7.22%.
1998: Subtotal (return on investment): $7,240,216; 1999: Subtotal
(return on investment): $6,964,412; 2000: Subtotal (return on
investment): $6,688,608; 2003: Subtotal (return on investment):
$5,861,196.
1-year's depreciation; 1998: $3,820,000; 1999: $3,820,000; 2000:
$3,820,000; 2003: $3,820,000.
1998: Total capital costs: $11,060,216; 1999: Total capital costs:
$10,784,412; 2000: Total capital costs: $10,508,608; 2003: Total
capital costs: $9,681,196.
Taxes; 1998: $2,561,569; 1999: $2,728,153; 2000: $1,940,147; 2003:
$2,644,861.
Operations and maintenance; 1998: $3,813,505; 1999: $3,521,370; 2000:
$2,643,929; 2003: $3,374,338.
1998: Total costs: $17,435,290; 1999: Total costs: $17,033,935; 2000:
Total costs: $15,092,684; 2003: Total costs: $15,700,395.
Net benefit; 1998: ($2,552,852); 1999: $5,201,787; 2000: $47,063,470;
2003: $7,931,459.
Percentage of project
on federal lands; 1998: 16%; 1999: 16%; 2000: 16%; 2003: 16%.
1998: Net benefit of federal lands: ($408,456); 1999: Net benefit of
federal lands: $832,286; 2000: Net benefit of federal lands:
$7,530,155; 2003: Net benefit of federal lands: $1,269,033.
Estimated return on investment; 1998: 4.67%; 1999: 12.61%; 2000:
58.02%; 2003: 16.99%.
Sources: Various agencies (data), GAO (analysis).
Notes: Owner: Portland General Electric.
FERC annual charges (2002): $7,087.
[End of table]
Table 21: North Umpqua, FERC License No. 1927:
Dollars in 2002 dollars.
Generation (kwh); 1998: 1,068,238,000; 1999: 1,151,767,000; 2000:
992,251,000; 2003: 1,067,051,000.
Price; 1998: $0.0293; 1999: $0.0379; 2000: $0.1333; 2003: $0.0441.
1998: Value of power: $31,314,358; 1999: Value of power: $43,665,405;
2000: Value of power: $132,227,847; 2003: Value of power: $47,048,493.
RCLPD; 1998: $449,780,000; 1999: $441,260,000; 2000: $432,740,000;
2003: $407,180,000.
Rate of return on investment; 1998: 7.22%; 1999: 7.22%; 2000: 7.22%;
2003: 7.22%.
1998: Subtotal (return on investment): $32,474,116; 1999: Subtotal
(return on investment): $31,858,972; 2000: Subtotal (return on
investment): $31,243,828; 2003: Subtotal (return on investment):
$29,398,396.
1-year's depreciation; 1998: $8,520,000; 1999: $8,520,000; 2000:
$8,520,000; 2003: $8,520,000.
1998: Total capital costs: $40,994,116; 1999: Total capital costs:
$40,378,972; 2000: Total capital costs: $39,763,828; 2003: Total
capital costs: $37,918,396.
Taxes; 1998: $2,665,609; 1999: $3,531,653; 2000: $2,919,663; 2003:
$3,098,631.
Operations and maintenance; 1998: $1,577,117; 1999: $4,486,202; 2000:
$4,607,187; 2003: $3,726,428.
1998: Total costs: $45,236,841; 1999: Total costs: $48,396,827; 2000:
Total costs: $47,290,678; 2003: Total costs: $44,743,455.
Net benefit; 1998: ($13,922,483); 1999: ($4,731,423); 2000:
$84,937,169; 2003: $2,305,039.
Percentage of project
on federal lands; 1998: 100%; 1999: 100%; 2000: 100%; 2003: 100%.
1998: Net benefit of federal lands: ($13,922,483); 1999: Net benefit of
federal lands: ($4,731,423); 2000: Net benefit of federal lands:
$84,937,169; 2003: Net benefit of federal lands: $2,305,039.
Estimated return on investment; 1998: 4.12%; 1999: 6.15%; 2000: 26.85%;
2003: 7.79%.
Sources: Various agencies (data), GAO (analysis).
Notes: Owner: Pacificorp.
FERC annual charges (2002): $107,525.
[End of table]
Table 22: Noxon Rapids, FERC License No. 2075:
Dollars in 2002 dollars.
Generation (kwh); 1998: 1,688,285,000; 1999: 1,896,663,000; 2000:
1,635,238,000; 2003: 1,996,970,000.
Price; 1998: $0.0293; 1999: $0.0379; 2000: $0.1333; 2003: $0.0441.
1998: Value of power: $49,490,433; 1999: Value of power: $71,905,653;
2000: Value of power: $217,912,605; 2003: Value of power: $88,050,552.
RCLPD; 1998: $624,740,000; 1999: $613,080,000; 2000: $601,420,000;
2003: $566,440,000.
Rate of return on investment; 1998: 7.22%; 1999: 7.22%; 2000: 7.22%;
2003: 7.22%.
1998: Subtotal (return on investment): $45,106,228; 1999: Subtotal
(return on investment): $44,264,376; 2000: Subtotal (return on
investment): $43,422,524; 2003: Subtotal (return on investment):
$40,896,968.
1-year's depreciation; 1998: $11,660,000; 1999: $11,660,000; 2000:
$11,660,000; 2003: $11,660,000.
1998: Total capital costs: $56,766,228; 1999: Total capital costs:
$55,924,376; 2000: Total capital costs: $55,082,524; 2003: Total
capital costs: $52,556,968.
Taxes; 1998: $4,451,279; 1999: $4,625,208; 2000: $1,345,019; 2003:
$4,538,243.
Operations and maintenance; 1998: $2,582,016; 1999: $3,156,814; 2000:
$4,040,562; 2003: $3,309,051.
1998: Total costs: $63,799,523; 1999: Total costs: $63,706,397; 2000:
Total costs: $60,468,104; 2003: Total costs: $60,404,263.
Net benefit; 1998: ($14,309,090); 1999: $8,199,255; 2000: $157,444,500;
2003: $27,646,289.
Percentage of project
on federal lands; 1998: 5%; 1999: 5%; 2000: 5%; 2003: 5%.
1998: Net benefit of federal lands: ($715,454); 1999: Net benefit of
federal lands: $409,963; 2000: Net benefit of federal lands:
$7,872,225; 2003: Net benefit of federal lands: $1,382,314.
Estimated return on investment; 1998: 4.93%; 1999: 8.56%; 2000: 33.40%;
2003: 12.10%.
Sources: Various agencies (data), GAO (analysis).
Notes: Owner: Avista.
FERC annual charges (2002): $21,880.
[End of table]
Table 23: Pit River, FERC License No. 233:
Dollars in 2002 dollars.
Generation (kwh); 1998: 2,421,714,000; 1999: 2,203,044,000; 2000:
1,973,926,000; 2003: 2,170,564,000.
Price; 1998: $0.0293; 1999: $0.0379; 2000: $0.1333; 2003: $0.0441.
1998: Value of power: $70,990,190; 1999: Value of power: $83,521,066;
2000: Value of power: $263,046,331; 2003: Value of power: $95,704,672.
RCLPD; 1998: $420,400,000; 1999: $408,800,000; 2000: $397,200,000;
2003: $362,400,000.
Rate of return on investment; 1998: 7.22%; 1999: 7.22%; 2000: 7.22%;
2003: 7.22%.
1998: Subtotal (return on investment): $30,352,880; 1999: Subtotal
(return on investment): $29,515,360; 2000: Subtotal (return on
investment): $28,677,840; 2003: Subtotal (return on investment):
$26,165,280.
1-year's depreciation; 1998: $11,600,000; 1999: $11,600,000; 2000:
$11,600,000; 2003: $11,600,000.
1998: Total capital costs: $41,952,880; 1999: Total capital costs:
$41,115,360; 2000: Total capital costs: $40,277,840; 2003: Total
capital costs: $37,765,280.
Taxes; 1998: $29,693,302; 1999: $24,054,781; 2000: ($54,304,717);
2003: $26,874,041.
Operations and maintenance; 1998: $6,244,151; 1999: $5,675,887; 2000:
$5,072,667; 2003: $5,746,843.
1998: Total costs: $77,890,332; 1999: Total costs: $70,846,028; 2000:
Total costs: ($8,954,211); 2003: Total costs: $70,386,164.
Net benefit; 1998: ($6,900,142); 1999: $12,675,038; 2000: $272,000,542;
2003: $25,318,508.
Percentage of project
on federal lands; 1998: 20%; 1999: 20%; 2000: 20%; 2003: 20%.
1998: Net benefit of federal lands: ($1,380,028); 1999: Net benefit of
federal lands: $2,535,008; 2000: Net benefit of federal lands:
$54,400,108; 2003: Net benefit of federal lands: $5,063,702.
Estimated return on investment; 1998: 5.58%; 1999: 10.32%; 2000:
75.70%; 2003: 14.21%.
Sources: Various agencies (data), GAO (analysis).
Notes: Owner: Pacific Gas and Electric.
FERC annual charges (2002): $49,448.
[End of table]
Table 24: Priest Rapids, FERC License No. 2114:
Dollars in 2002 dollars.
Generation (kwh); 1998: 9,432,280,000; 1999: 11,314,265,000; 2000:
9,621,814,000; 2003: 10,671,292,000.
Price; 1998: $0.0293; 1999: $0.0379; 2000: $0.1333; 2003: $0.0441.
1998: Value of power: $276,498,114; 1999: Value of power: $428,942,626;
2000: Value of power: $1,282,207,576; 2003: Value of power:
$470,519,412.
RCLPD; 1998: $857,620,000; 1999: $819,840,000; 2000: $782,060,000;
2003: $668,720,000.
Rate of return on investment; 1998: 7.22%; 1999: 7.22%; 2000: 7.22%;
2003: 7.22%.
1998: Subtotal (return on investment): $61,920,164; 1999: Subtotal
(return on investment): $59,192,448; 2000: Subtotal (return on
investment): $56,464,732; 2003: Subtotal (return on investment):
$48,281,584.
1-year's depreciation; 1998: $37,780,000; 1999: $37,780,000; 2000:
$37,780,000; 2003: $37,780,000.
1998: Total capital costs: $99,700,164; 1999: Total capital costs:
$96,972,448; 2000: Total capital costs: $94,244,732; 2003: Total
capital costs: $86,061,584.
Taxes; 1998: $7,637,605; 1999: $8,356,892; 2000: $8,652,931; 2003:
$7,997,248.
Operations and maintenance; 1998: $23,349,213; 1999: $22,000,357;
2000: $25,281,673; 2003: $23,882,666.
1998: Total costs: $130,686,981; 1999: Total costs: $127,329,696; 2000:
Total costs: $128,179,336; 2003: Total costs: $117,941,498.
Net benefit; 1998: $145,811,132; 1999: $301,612,930; 2000:
$1,154,028,240; 2003: $352,577,914.
Percentage of project
on federal lands; 1998: 8%; 1999: 8%; 2000: 8%; 2003: 8%.
1998: Net benefit of federal lands: $11,664,891; 1999: Net benefit of
federal lands: $24,129,034; 2000: Net benefit of federal lands:
$92,322,259; 2003: Net benefit of federal lands: $28,206,233.
Estimated return on investment; 1998: 24.22%; 1999: 44.01%; 2000:
154.78%; 2003: 59.94%.
Sources: Various agencies (data), GAO (analysis).
Notes: Owner: Grant County Public Utility District.
FERC annual charges (2002): $49,262.
[End of table]
Table 25: Rock Island, FERC License No. 943:
Dollars in 2002 dollars.
Generation (kwh); 1998: 2,567,863,600; 1999: 3,184,966,500; 2000:
2,747,085,000; 2003: 2,938,037,000.
Price; 1998: $0.0293; 1999: $0.0379; 2000: $0.1333; 2003: $0.0441.
1998: Value of power: $75,274,424; 1999: Value of power: $120,747,384;
2000: Value of power: $366,077,873; 2003: Value of power: $129,544,149.
RCLPD; 1998: $397,600,000; 1999: $383,400,000; 2000: $369,200,000;
2003: $326,600,000.
Rate of return on investment; 1998: 7.22%; 1999: 7.22%; 2000: 7.22%;
2003: 7.22%.
1998: Subtotal (return on investment): $28,706,720; 1999: Subtotal
(return on investment): $27,681,480; 2000: Subtotal (return on
investment): $26,656,240; 2003: Subtotal (return on investment):
$23,580,520.
1-year's depreciation; 1998: $14,200,000; 1999: $14,200,000; 2000:
$14,200,000; 2003: $14,200,000.
1998: Total capital costs: $42,906,720; 1999: Total capital costs:
$41,881,480; 2000: Total capital costs: $40,856,240; 2003: Total
capital costs: $37,780,520.
Taxes; 1998: $2,167,707; 1999: $1,870,624; 2000: $1,588,846; 2003:
$2,019,166.
Operations and maintenance; 1998: $16,274,989; 1999: $17,364,417;
2000: $15,436,263; 2003: $16,561,592.
1998: Total costs: $61,349,416; 1999: Total costs: $61,116,521; 2000:
Total costs: $57,881,350; 2003: Total costs: $56,361,278.
Net benefit; 1998: $13,925,008; 1999: $59,630,862; 2000: $308,196,523;
2003: $73,182,871.
Percentage of project
on federal lands; 1998: 1%; 1999: 1%; 2000: 1%; 2003: 1%.
1998: Net benefit of federal lands: $139,250; 1999: Net benefit of
federal lands: $596,309; 2000: Net benefit of federal lands:
$3,081,965; 2003: Net benefit of federal lands: $731,829.
Estimated return on investment; 1998: 10.72%; 1999: 22.77%; 2000:
90.70%; 2003: 29.63%.
Sources: Various agencies (data), GAO (analysis).
Notes: Owner: Chelan County Public Utility District.
FERC annual charges (2002): $628.
[End of table]
Table 26: Rocky Reach, FERC License No. 2145:
Dollars in 2002 dollars.
Generation (kwh); 1998: 5,963,472,049; 1999: 7,425,230,613; 2000:
6,288,474,000; 2003: 6,694,102,000.
Price; 1998: $0.0293; 1999: $0.0379; 2000: $0.1333; 2003: $0.0441.
1998: Value of power: $174,813,383; 1999: Value of power: $281,502,857;
2000: Value of power: $838,005,079; 2003: Value of power: $295,156,851.
RCLPD; 1998: $737,600,000; 1999: $720,800,000; 2000: $704,000,000;
2003: $653,600,000.
Rate of return on investment; 1998: 7.22%; 1999: 7.22%; 2000: 7.22%;
2003: 7.22%.
1998: Subtotal (return on investment): $53,254,720; 1999: Subtotal
(return on investment): $52,041,760; 2000: Subtotal (return on
investment): $50,828,800; 2003: Subtotal (return on investment):
$47,189,920.
1-year's depreciation; 1998: $16,800,000; 1999: $16,800,000; 2000:
$16,800,000; 2003: $16,800,000.
1998: Total capital costs: $70,054,720; 1999: Total capital costs:
$68,841,760; 2000: Total capital costs: $67,628,800; 2003: Total
capital costs: $63,989,920.
Taxes; 1998: $5,034,170; 1999: $4,361,056; 2000: $3,637,099; 2003:
$4,697,613.
Operations and maintenance; 1998: $22,186,765; 1999: $26,363,109;
2000: $25,907,624; 2003: $25,154,953.
1998: Total costs: $97,275,655; 1999: Total costs: $99,565,925; 2000:
Total costs: $97,173,523; 2003: Total costs: $93,842,486.
Net benefit; 1998: $77,537,728; 1999: $181,936,931; 2000: $740,831,556;
2003: $201,314,365.
Percentage of project
on federal lands; 1998: 1%; 1999: 1%; 2000: 1%; 2003: 1%.
1998: Net benefit of federal lands: $775,377; 1999: Net benefit of
federal lands: $1,819,369; 2000: Net benefit of federal lands:
$7,408,316; 2003: Net benefit of federal lands: $2,013,144.
Estimated return on investment; 1998: 17.73%; 1999: 32.46%; 2000:
112.45%; 2003: 38.02%.
Sources: Various agencies (data), GAO (analysis).
Notes: Owner: Chelan County Public Utility District.
FERC annual charges (2002): $2,580.
[End of table]
Table 27: Skagit River, FERC License No. 553:
Dollars in 2002 dollars.
Generation (kwh); 1998: 2,182,773,373; 1999: 3,165,975,767; 2000:
2,510,464,000; 2003: 2,766,407,000.
Price; 1998: $0.0293; 1999: $0.0379; 2000: $0.1333; 2003: $0.0441.
1998: Value of power: $63,985,878; 1999: Value of power: $120,027,413;
2000: Value of power: $334,545,644; 2003: Value of power: $121,976,626.
RCLPD; 1998: $783,520,000; 1999: $767,890,000; 2000: $752,260,000;
2003: $705,370,000.
Rate of return on investment; 1998: 7.22%; 1999: 7.22%; 2000: 7.22%;
2003: 7.22%.
1998: Subtotal (return on investment): $56,570,144; 1999: Subtotal
(return on investment): $55,441,658; 2000: Subtotal (return on
investment): $54,313,172; 2003: Subtotal (return on investment):
$50,927,714.
1-year's depreciation; 1998: $15,630,000; 1999: $15,630,000; 2000:
$15,630,000; 2003: $15,630,000.
1998: Total capital costs: $72,200,144; 1999: Total capital costs:
$71,071,658; 2000: Total capital costs: $69,943,172; 2003: Total
capital costs: $66,557,714.
Taxes; 1998: $13,130,607; 1999: $15,364,581; 2000: $16,744,282; 2003:
$14,247,594.
Operations and maintenance; 1998: $11,499,148; 1999: $11,748,608;
2000: $11,948,450; 2003: $11,890,426.
1998: Total costs: $96,829,899; 1999: Total costs: $98,184,846; 2000:
Total costs: $98,635,904; 2003: Total costs: $92,695,734.
Net benefit; 1998: ($32,844,021); 1999: $21,842,567; 2000:
$235,909,740; 2003: $29,280,892.
Percentage of project
on federal lands; 1998: 70%; 1999: 70%; 2000: 70%; 2003: 70%.
1998: Net benefit of federal lands: ($22,990,815); 1999: Net benefit of
federal lands: $15,289,797; 2000: Net benefit of federal lands:
$165,136,818; 2003: Net benefit of federal lands: $20,496,624.
Estimated return on investment; 1998: 3.03%; 1999: 10.06%; 2000:
38.58%; 2003: 11.37%.
Sources: Various agencies (data), GAO (analysis).
Notes: Owner: City of Seattle.
FERC annual charges (2002): $917,001.
[End of table]
Table 28: Swift, FERC License No. 2111:
Dollars in 2002 dollars.
Generation (kwh); 1998: 738,349,000; 1999: 912,943,000; 2000:
629,872,000; 2003: 824,169,000.
Price; 1998: $0.0293; 1999: $0.0379; 2000: $0.1333; 2003: $0.0441.
1998: Value of power: $21,643,983; 1999: Value of power: $34,611,189;
2000: Value of power: $83,937,047; 2003: Value of power: $36,339,322.
RCLPD; 1998: $252,800,000; 1999: $247,350,000; 2000: $241,900,000;
2003: $225,550,000.
Rate of return on investment; 1998: 7.22%; 1999: 7.22%; 2000: 7.22%;
2003: 7.22%.
1998: Subtotal (return on investment): $18,252,160; 1999: Subtotal
(return on investment): $17,858,670; 2000: Subtotal (return on
investment): $17,465,180; 2003: Subtotal (return on investment):
$16,284,710.
1-year's depreciation; 1998: $5,450,000; 1999: $5,450,000; 2000:
$5,450,000; 2003: $5,450,000.
1998: Total capital costs: $23,702,160; 1999: Total capital costs:
$23,308,670; 2000: Total capital costs: $22,915,180; 2003: Total
capital costs: $21,734,710.
Taxes; 1998: $1,842,426; 1999: $2,799,349; 2000: $1,853,376; 2003:
$2,320,888.
Operations and maintenance; 1998: $1,729,340; 1999: $3,196,729; 2000:
$3,016,732; 2003: $2,755,581.
1998: Total costs: $27,273,926; 1999: Total costs: $29,304,748; 2000:
Total costs: $27,785,288; 2003: Total costs: $26,811,179.
Net benefit; 1998: ($5,629,944); 1999: $5,306,441; 2000: $56,151,759;
2003: $9,528,143.
Percentage of project
on federal lands; 1998: 6%; 1999: 6%; 2000: 6%; 2003: 6%.
1998: Net benefit of federal lands: ($337,797); 1999: Net benefit of
federal lands: $318,386; 2000: Net benefit of federal lands:
$3,369,106; 2003: Net benefit of federal lands: $571,689.
Estimated return on investment; 1998: 4.99%; 1999: 9.37%; 2000: 30.43%;
2003: 11.44%.
Sources: Various agencies (data), GAO (analysis).
Notes: Owner: Pacificorp.
FERC annual charges (2002): $18,651.
[End of table]
Table 29: Thompson Falls, FERC License No. 1869:
Dollars in 2002 dollars.
Generation (kwh); 1998: 505,681,000; 1999: 523,358,957; 2000:
506,722,000; 2003: 497,759,000.
Price; 1998: $0.0293; 1999: $0.0379; 2000: $0.1333; 2003: $0.0441.
1998: Value of power: $14,823,547; 1999: Value of power: $19,841,410;
2000: Value of power: $67,526,018; 2003: Value of power: $21,947,227.
RCLPD; 1998: $121,940,000; 1999: $118,430,000; 2000: $114,920,000;
2003: $104,390,000.
Rate of return on investment; 1998: 7.22%; 1999: 7.22%; 2000: 7.22%;
2003: 7.22%.
1998: Subtotal (return on investment): $8,804,068; 1999: Subtotal
(return on investment): $8,550,646; 2000: Subtotal (return on
investment): $8,297,224; 2003: Subtotal (return on investment):
$7,536,958.
1-year's depreciation; 1998: $3,510,000; 1999: $3,510,000; 2000:
$3,510,000; 2003: $3,510,000.
1998: Total capital costs: $12,314,068; 1999: Total capital costs:
$12,060,646; 2000: Total capital costs: $11,807,224; 2003: Total
capital costs: $11,046,958.
Taxes; 1998: $3,511,088; 1999: $3,642,339; 2000: $2,238,251; 2003:
$3,576,713.
Operations and maintenance; 1998: $1,234,231; 1999: $966,774; 2000:
$1,006,853; 2003: $1,082,540.
1998: Total costs: $17,059,387; 1999: Total costs: $16,669,759; 2000:
Total costs: $15,052,328; 2003: Total costs: $15,706,211.
Net benefit; 1998: ($2,235,840); 1999: $3,171,651; 2000: $52,473,690;
2003: $6,241,016.
Percentage of project
on federal lands; 1998: 11%; 1999: 11%; 2000: 11%; 2003: 11%.
1998: Net benefit of federal lands: ($245,942); 1999: Net benefit of
federal lands: $348,882; 2000: Net benefit of federal lands:
$5,772,106; 2003: Net benefit of federal lands: $686,512.
Estimated return on investment; 1998: 5.39%; 1999: 9.90%; 2000: 52.88%;
2003: 13.20%.
Sources: Various agencies (data), GAO (analysis).
Notes: Owner: PP&L Montana.
FERC annual charges (2002): $4,043.
[End of table]
Table 30: Upper American River Project, FERC License No. 2101:
Dollars in 2002 dollars.
Generation (kwh); 1998: 2,818,100,622; 1999: 2,317,979,622; 2000:
1,944,354,622; 2003: 2,476,064,622.
Price; 1998: $0.0293; 1999: $0.0379; 2000: $0.1333; 2003: $0.0441.
1998: Value of power: $82,609,879; 1999: Value of power: $87,878,467;
2000: Value of power: $259,105,635; 2003: Value of power: $109,174,828.
RCLPD; 1998: $1,377,020,000; 1999: $1,338,290,000; 2000:
$1,299,560,000; 2003: $1,183,370,000.
Rate of return on investment; 1998: 7.22%; 1999: 7.22%; 2000: 7.22%;
2003: 7.22%.
1998: Subtotal (return on investment): $99,420,844; 1999: Subtotal
(return on investment): $96,624,538; 2000: Subtotal (return on
investment): $93,828,232; 2003: Subtotal (return on investment):
$85,439,314.
1-year's depreciation; 1998: $38,730,000; 1999: $38,730,000; 2000:
$38,730,000; 2003: $38,730,000.
1998: Total capital costs: $138,150,844; 1999: Total capital costs:
$135,354,538; 2000: Total capital costs: $132,558,232; 2003: Total
capital costs: $124,169,314.
Taxes; 1998: $103,413; 1999: $93,043; 2000: $49,249; 2003: $98,228.
Operations and maintenance; 1998: $10,759,147; 1999: $10,641,772;
2000: $10,080,115; 2003: $10,627,978.
1998: Total costs: $149,013,405; 1999: Total costs: $146,089,352; 2000:
Total costs: $142,687,596; 2003: Total costs: $134,895,520.
Net benefit; 1998: ($66,403,526); 1999: ($58,210,885); 2000:
$116,418,039; 2003: ($25,720,692).
Percentage of project
on federal lands; 1998: 59%; 1999: 59%; 2000: 59%; 2003: 59%.
1998: Net benefit of federal lands: ($39,178,080); 1999: Net benefit of
federal lands: ($34,344,422); 2000: Net benefit of federal lands:
$68,686,643; 2003: Net benefit of federal lands: ($15,175,208).
Estimated return on investment; 1998: 2.40%; 1999: 2.87%; 2000: 16.18%;
2003: 5.05%.
Sources: Various agencies (data), GAO (analysis).
Notes: Owner: Sacramento Municipal Utility District.
FERC annual charges (2002): $285,804.
[End of table]
Table 31: Upper North Fork Feather River, FERC License No. 2105:
Dollars in 2002 dollars.
Generation (kwh); 1998: 1,524,166,457; 1999: 1,297,626,219; 2000:
1,251,223,000; 2003: 1,482,681,522.
Price; 1998: $0.0293; 1999: $0.0379; 2000: $0.1333; 2003: $0.0441.
1998: Value of power: $44,679,457; 1999: Value of power: $49,195,171;
2000: Value of power: $166,738,581; 2003: Value of power: $65,374,506.
RCLPD; 1998: $417,360,000; 1999: $406,070,000; 2000: $394,780,000;
2003: $360,910,000.
Rate of return on investment; 1998: 7.22%; 1999: 7.22%; 2000: 7.22%;
2003: 7.22%.
1998: Subtotal (return on investment): $30,133,392; 1999: Subtotal
(return on investment): $29,318,254; 2000: Subtotal (return on
investment): $28,503,116; 2003: Subtotal (return on investment):
$26,057,702.
1-year's depreciation; 1998: $11,290,000; 1999: $11,290,000; 2000:
$11,290,000; 2003: $11,290,000.
1998: Total capital costs: $41,423,392; 1999: Total capital costs:
$40,608,254; 2000: Total capital costs: $39,793,116; 2003: Total
capital costs: $37,347,702.
Taxes; 1998: $18,688,224; 1999: $14,168,630; 2000: ($34,422,421);
2003: $16,428,427.
Operations and maintenance; 1998: $6,233,997; 1999: $7,331,316; 2000:
$5,462,547; 2003: $6,431,826.
1998: Total costs: $66,345,614; 1999: Total costs: $62,108,200; 2000:
Total costs: $10,833,243; 2003: Total costs: $60,207,955.
Net benefit; 1998: ($21,666,156); 1999: ($12,913,029); 2000:
$155,905,338; 2003: $5,166,551.
Percentage of project
on federal lands; 1998: 4%; 1999: 4%; 2000: 4%; 2003: 4%.
1998: Net benefit of federal lands: ($866,646); 1999: Net benefit of
federal lands: ($516,521); 2000: Net benefit of federal lands:
$6,236,214; 2003: Net benefit of federal lands: $206,662.
Estimated return on investment; 1998: 2.03%; 1999: 4.04%; 2000: 46.71%;
2003: 8.65%.
Sources: Various agencies (data), GAO (analysis).
Notes: Owner: Pacific Gas and Electric.
FERC annual charges (2002): $85,389.
[End of table]
[End of section]
Appendix III: Comments from the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission:
FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION WASHINGTON, DC 20426:
OFFICE OF THE CHAIRMAN:
April 2, 2003:
Mr. Barry T. Hill Director:
Natural Resources and Environment U.S. General Accounting Office 441 G
Street, N.W.
Washington, D.C. 20548:
Re: FERC's Comments on GAO Draft Report, GAO-03-383:
Dear Mr. Hill:
Thank you for giving us the opportunity to respond to your draft report
entitled "Charges for Hydropower Projects' Use of Federal Lands Need to
Be Reassessed." We feel that this report highlighted many of the issues
surrounding land valuations and was a laudable effort in analyzing such
a difficult subject.
Section 10(e)(1) of the Federal Power Act requires the Commission to
collect from its hydropower licensees reasonable annual charges to
recompense the United States for a project's use, occupancy, and
enjoyment of federal lands, but to seek to avoid increasing the price
to the consumers of the project power. The Commission has used an
assessment system based on a schedule of right-of-way values developed
by the U.S. Forest Service and Bureau of Land Management. These values
are based on local surveys of market values for the various types of
land that has been allowed to be occupied by linear rights-of-way and
the fees are calculated on a per-acre basis by state and county.
The draft report identifies an alternative method to recover
compensation for a project licensee's use of federal lands. The method
employed a "net benefits" analysis. Using a sample of licensed
projects, its analysis produced values in orders of magnitude far
exceeding those calculated under the right-of-way system. The GAO
method also showed extreme variations in year-to-year charges. Both of
these results are reasons for GAO to reconsider the validity of its
method.
The draft report provides sound recommendations on how the Commission's
databases containing information on federal lands should be managed.
These databases were established independently for different purposes.
We are reviewing the specifics of these recommendations and will
implement the improvements as soon as possible.
I have enclosed an appendix with staff comments on the report. If you
have any questions concerning our comments, please contact John R.
Paquin at (202) 502-6003.
Best regards,
Pat Wood, III
Chairman:
Signed by Pat Wood, III:
Enclosure:
FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION:
STAFF COMMENTS ON DRAFT REPORT ENTITLED "Charges for Hydropower
Projects' Use of Federal Lands Need to Be Reassessed":
General Comments:
1. The net benefits methodology employed in calculating the fair market
value of the lands occupied by the sample set of 24 licensed projects
yielded values that in many cases far exceeded the values calculated
under the current right-of-way methodology. One striking example is the
Hells Canyon Project in Idaho. Ninety percent of lands within the
project boundary are federal. In FY 2002, we collected annual charges
of $371,000 while between 1998 and 2000, under the net benefits
approach, the annual value for the use of federal lands was estimated
to range from $111,336,000 to $602,751,000. We question how charges
based on such extreme valuations could be considered "reasonable.":
2. Utilizing the net benefits analysis technique would require the
Commission to begin collecting additional data that is currently
collected only from some licensees, or is not currently required to be
filed. Data on project operating costs and expenses, overhead expenses,
and replacement costs generally are not available and may be reported
differently using different assumptions and accounting practices.
Under-the net benefits methodology, the Commission staff would have to
recalculate much of the data each year. Moreover, additional burden
would be placed on licensees to supply some of this information.
Additional staff and resources would be required to perform these
analyses and to recalculate the amounts each year.
3. The draft report states that the Commission does not verify the
federal acreage within the project boundary reported by licensees in
their applications. Federal land management agencies are active
participants, and sometimes cooperating agencies in our licensing/
relicensing and NEPA processes. Public notices are issued giving the
agencies the opportunity to review the reported acreage figures and
location of these lands. Any disagreements are worked out by the agency
and applicant before the Commission establishes the charges.
4. GAO conducted its net benefits analysis using a stratified sample of
24 projects that accounted for about 60 percent of the power generated
by projects that occupy federal lands. Moreover, the sample set of 24
was drawn from a set of 56 projects that represent about 90 percent of
the power-generated at projects
occupying federal lands. These 56 projects represent 5.5 percent of the
total licensed projects under the Commission's Jurisdiction. That
leaves 117 projects on federal lands that generate the remaining 10
percent of the power. We must also consider the time and resources
required to conduct economic analyses that involve such a small number
of projects. The same detailed analysis would have to be applied to the
117 projects that only contribute 10 percent of the power.
5. The draft report acknowledges that the value of the federal land can
change dramatically with a significant change in supply and demand for
electricity. The wholesale price of electricity, one of the key factors
in the net benefit methodology, is governed by supply and demand
factors. In addition, the draft report lists other uncertainties like
changes in weather, regulatory constraints, and cost of fuels that can
affect electricity markets. Licensees would be placed in the very
difficult position of having to plan and budget their resources to
respond to wide variations in annual charge bills, which would place an
increased burden on all licensees.
Specific Comments:
Page 14, 3rd paragraph - The statement that FERC databases with
information on federal lands contain "conflicting information" is
misleading. These databases were set up independently for different
purposes and the perceived inconsistencies reflect this fact. For
example, the Commission does not issue bills or collect charges from
most of the approximately 10 licensed projects that occupy Indian
tribal reservations, because it approved settlement agreements that
provided for lump-sum payments or payments that the licensee makes
directly to the tribes. Also, the Commission does not assess federal
land use charges for the federal lands underlying a federal dam used by
a licensed project; instead, the licensee pays a federal dam use
charge.
Nevertheless, we agree that integrating portions of these systems would
increase accuracy and efficiency for all users. Presently, the
Commission is developing requirements for a Commission-wide tracking
and management system that includes, as one of its primary goals, the
functional integration of associated and duplicative systems.
Page 28, 3 bullets - The suggestions on how to mitigate the effects on
consumers of assessing rates close to or equal to fair market values
ignore the difficulty in setting different rates for each of the 173
projects that would be considered to be reasonable, in light of the
number-of variables GAO has identified as affecting the calculation of
fair market value. This would be an extremely complex undertaking that
would almost guarantee a significant number of disputed bills and
administrative hearings to resolve them.
Page 48, 3rd full paragraph - GAO acknowledges the "wide variety of
characteristics that determine the value and costs of any particular
dam." We accept the fact that any change to our methodology of
calculating land use charges would open the door to challenge. But to
impose a system based on complex economic analyses based on so many
assumptions would almost certainly result in costly challenges and
appeals. One example is the actual contribution the government lands
make to the project. How do you factor that into the equation and
fairly access each licensee?
Page 62 - Under the GAO net benefits methodology, the percentage of a
project's total acreage that is federal is a key consideration in its
calculations. What matters is not the percentage that is federal, but
the value of what such lands contribute to the project's economic
benefits.
The following are GAO's comments on the Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission's letter dated April 2, 2003.
GAO's Comments:
1. We disagree. As we discuss, the value of federal land varied because
the wholesale price of electricity varied during the 3 years we
reviewed---not because our analysis was flawed. Furthermore, even the
lowest of our estimates of the value of federal lands used for
hydropower demonstrates that FERC's current annual charge system is
getting less than 2 percent of the land's hydropower value. We shared
these results in detail with high-level FERC officials---including
FERC's Executive Director--in September 2002 and February 2003. In
contrast to their written comments, FERC officials at those meetings
indicated that they had no analytical disagreement with our analysis,
and as we indicate in our report, the Executive Director agreed that a
reassessment of FERC's current annual charge system would be
appropriate.
2. We do not specifically recommend that FERC use a net benefits
approach as a mechanism for levying annual charges. However, we do
recommend that FERC consider the hydropower value of the land--as well
as the Federal Power Act's other competing goals of encouraging the
development of hydropower and avoiding unreasonable rate increases to
consumers--to develop a reasonable annual charge. As we reported,
FERC's annual charge system is based on a fee schedule that was not
designed for hydropower uses, and that does not accurately assess fair
market value for the fee schedule's original intended purpose. FERC did
not address these shortcomings in its comments. Moreover, because FERC
officials have not analyzed the value of federal lands used to produce
hydropower for more than 15 years, it is difficult for FERC to address
such questions as (1) what is the fair market value of these lands,
(2) how much does FERC need to discount from fair market value to
adequately encourage the development of hydropower, and (3) at what
point would annual charges based on the fair market value result in
unreasonable rate increases to consumers. After completing such an
analysis FERC will be in a better position to determine what annual
charges are reasonable.
3. As mentioned in comment 2, we do not specifically recommend that
FERC adopt a net benefits approach. We recognize that in reassessing
its current annual charge system, by whatever method it uses, FERC may
have to consider the administrative burden it may pose for itself and
licensees. In the end, FERC has to consider the costs and benefits of
revising its current system. Since our estimates indicate that the
federal lands are worth hundreds of millions of dollars annually, it is
likely worthwhile for FERC to expend more resources than it does under
its existing system. Regarding licensees, FERC currently requires many
licensees to report an enormous amount of data in its annual FERC Form
1 submissions. For several licensees in our sample, the completed form
was more than an inch thick. In our view, FERC has not demonstrated
that requiring licensees to provide additional data would significantly
increase the existing burden on licensees. (See also comment 5.):
4. We disagree with FERC's apparent assertion that the federal land
management agencies--not FERC--are responsible for determining the
amount of federal acreage to levy an annual charge, and that through
the process of issuing a public notice, federal land management
agencies and the license applicant will resolve any questions about the
number of federal acres involved. We have two concerns about this
assertion. First, under the Federal Power Act, developing and executing
an annual charge system is FERC's responsibility--not that of the
federal land management agencies'. Accordingly, FERC should ensure that
it has accurate and verified information on the amount of federal acres
that licensees should be charged for using. Second, if FERC wants the
federal land management agencies to verify federal acreage, then FERC
needs to formally communicate this task to the agencies, develop
mutually agreed to protocols, and confirm that the work was completed.
According to officials from the Forest Service and the Department of
the Interior, none of these actions have occurred.
5. See comment 2. In addition, we do not recommend that FERC perform a
net benefit analysis every year on all projects that use federal lands.
Finally, if FERC reassesses its current annual charge system, it needs
to decide which valuation tools to use, how to balance the competing
goals of the Federal Power Act, and what revisions to make.
6. If FERC decides to reassess and revise its annual charge system, it
does not have to use an annual charge system that fluctuates with
electricity markets. FERC can make decisions on the basis of long-term
expectations that would tend to mitigate short-term volatility. In the
past, FERC has approved annual charges for tribal lands that (1) were
based on a long-term analysis of the value for the use of the land and
(2) were a fixed amount so that licensees could plan and budget
for them.
7. We disagree that our presentation of issues regarding the databases
supporting FERC's annual charge program is "misleading." Even though
these databases were established for varying reasons, FERC still has to
correct conflicting information. However, as discussed in the report,
the databases for several cases we reviewed contained conflicting
billing or federal acreage information that we could not resolve. More
importantly, FERC staff had difficulty resolving this conflicting
information, and in some cases never did.
8. FERC appears to agree with our essential point that, in valuing
federal lands, what matters is how much these lands contribute to the
project's economic benefit. The value of the economic contribution of
federal lands to hydropower production forms the basis for the approach
we took in this report. We recognize that for many of the projects in
our sample, a portion of the acreage is owned by the federal government
and the remainder is owned by other parties. For our analysis, we
multiplied the value to hydropower production of all lands in each
project by the percentage of the project owned by the federal
government. However, if FERC can differentiate between project lands
that are more or less important in producing economic value, then FERC
would be justified in setting annual charges accordingly.
[End of section]
Appendix IV Comments from the National Hydropower Association:
National Hydropower Association:
One Massachusetts Ave., NW Suite 850:
Washington, DC 20001:
Tel 202-682-1700 Fax: 202-682-9478 www.hydro.org:
March 31, 2003:
Mr. Barry T. Hill Director:
Natural Resources and Environment U.S. General Accounting Office 441 G
Street, N.W.
Washington, D.C. 20548:
Re: Comments of the National Hydropower Association (NHA) and Western
Public Power Entities on the General Accounting Office's (GAO) Draft
Report on Federal Land Use Fees:
Dear Mr. Hill:
Please find enclosed the comments of NHA and the Western Public Power
Entities on GAO's Draft Report entitled, "Charges for Hydropower
Projects' Use of Federal Lands Need to be Reassessed, March 2003, (GAO-
03-383)." NHA and the Western Public Power Entities appreciate the
opportunity to respond to this important report.
Sincerely,
Linda Church Ciocci
Executive Director
National Hydropower Association
One Massachusetts Ave., N.W. Suite 850:
Signed by Linda Church Ciocci:
Washington, D.C. 20001 (202) 298-1800:
Steven Richardson, Esq.
Van Ness Feldman, P.C.
1050 Thomas Jefferson Street
Seventh Floor
Washington, DC 20007 (202) 682-1700:
March 31, 2003:
Mr. Barry T. Hill Director:
Natural Resources and Environment U.S. General Accounting Office 441 G
Street, N.W.
Washington, D.C. 20548:
Re: Comments of the National Hydropower Association (NHA) on the
General Accounting Office's (GAO) Report on Federal Land Use Fees:
Dear Mr. Hill:
The National Hydropower Association thanks you and your staff for the
opportunity to review and comment on the GAO's Draft Report entitled,
"Charges for Hydropower Projects' Use of Federal Lands Need to be
Reassessed, March 2003, (GAO-03-383)." NHA appreciates the opportunity
to comment on this important report affecting the hydropower industry.
As you know, NHA is the national trade association committed
exclusively to representing the interests of the hydroelectric power
industry. Our members represent 61 percent of domestic, non-federal
hydroelectric capacity and nearly 80,000 megawatts overall in North
America. NHA's membership consists of more than 140 organizations
including; public utilities, investor owned utilities, independent
power producers, equipment manufacturers, environmental and
engineering consultants and attorneys.
Sincerely,
Linda Church Ciocci
Executive Director
National Hydropower Association
One Massachusetts Ave., N.W. Suite 850
Washington, D.C. 20001 (202) 682-1700:
Signed by Linda Church Ciocci:
COMMENTS OF THE NATIONAL HYDROPOWER ASSOCIATION ON THE GAO REPORT TO
CONGRESS ON FEDERAL LAND USE FEES FOR HYDROPOWER PROJECTS:
MARCH 31, 2003:
INTRODUCTION:
The National Hydropower Association (NHA) submits the following
comments to the United States General Accounting Office (GAO) on its
draft report to Congress entitled, "Charges for Hydropower Projects'
Use of Federal Lands Need to be Reassessed (GAO-03-383)." NHA
appreciates the opportunity to comment on the draft report for
inclusion in the final report that is forwarded to Congress by GAO.
[NOTE 1]
MAJOR CONCERNS AND CONCLUSIONS:
* GAO's methodology, if adopted, could easily increase retail rates to
consumers, particularly in the West, by hundreds of millions of dollars
per year. These are consumers who are still reeling from the energy
crisis that affected the entire western region of the United States in
2001.
* GAO's methodology could produce highly volatile land use charges and
could generate significant uncertainty in its application. Should the
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) follow GAO's example and
implement this methodology, FERC would require new staff resources and
lengthy dispute resolution procedures. The new system would also impose
a significant administrative burden on the industry to develop the
paperwork necessary for FERC to set the new fees.
* GAO's methodology is technically flawed. It produces negative "net
benefits", yet does not propose that FERC pay licensees under such
circumstances. It could produce annual land use charges that could vary
by many orders of magnitude from one year to the next. It relies on
market price indices recently judged to have been manipulated by market
participants. It assumes that all economic rents should be allocated
only for land, and not for other fixed inputs such as the investments
made by project licensees on behalf of their consumers. Finally, it
does not take into account the public benefits already provided by
licensees under license conditions, including parks, recreational
opportunities, and fisheries enhancement. In essence, GAO's methodology
would permit the federal government to collect twice; once through
license conditions and another time through land use charges. This
methodology simply does not represent "fair market value.":
* The GAO methodology is inconsistent with federal policies on
hydropower. Its adoption would be a step in the wrong direction,
particularly in light of all the work underway in Congress
to resolve problems facing the hydropower resource and provide
incentives for new development. Considering the nation's need for more
renewable energy, now is not the time to
pursue policies that would undermine hydropower's role as the nation's
leading renewable energy source.
BACKGROUND:
Non-federal hydropower owners and operators whose projects are fully or
partially located on federal land pay rent for the use of the public
land. These land use charges are administered by the Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission (FERC). The Federal Power Act (FPA) gives FERC
the authority to collect these charges. FERC was not directed to obtain
"fair market value" for the land. Instead, FERC was authorized to
establish "reasonable" fees that balance land use with the public
benefits of low cost and abundant supplies of energy.
In the 1990's, a FERC rulemaking explored several options to set
charges for using public lands. After due deliberation, FERC adopted
the U.S. Forest Service's fee system for linear rights of way on
National Forest System land. The Forest Service zonal fee system
annually produces a per acre charge on a county-by-county basis for
every state. The zonal fees were prepared for homogeneous regions based
on ROW appraisal information furnished by the utility industry. FERC
charges the same fee as the Forest Service for transmission lines, and
twice that amount for other federal land used within a hydropower
project boundary.
In late 2000, the GAO agreed to a request by the Interior and Energy
and Water Development Subcommittees of the House Appropriations
Committee to prepare a report on federal land use charges for
hydropower projects licensed by FERC. GAO shared a draft report with
NHA for comment on March 17tH and 19th of 2003. In its report, GAO
asserts that the current charges applied to FERC-licensed hydropower
projects do not represent a "fair market value" for the use of such
public lands.
GAO's draft report suggests that FERC reassess its system of annual
charges in light of: 1) information it provides concerning the
estimated value of the contribution federal lands make to hydropower
production; 2) the trend toward the restructuring of the nation's
electric markets; and 3) flaws in the present system. The GAO also
recommends that FERC develop new strategies for assessing annual
charges commensurate with the benefits licensees receive. In conducting
this reassessment, GAO suggests FERC determine methods for estimating
"fair market value" of federal lands, and determine methods for
assessing annual charges, taking into account the fair market value of
the federal lands, while also achieving the competing goals of
encouraging hydro development and avoiding unreasonable increases in
electric rates to consumers.
NHA strongly believes the draft report is flawed and that the GAO's
methodology is not applicable to determining the value of federal lands
to a FERC-licensed hydropower project. Fair market value, as determined
by a "net benefits" calculation, is not an appropriate means of
determining land use charges for federal lands. Though GAO does not
recommend that FERC adopt its approach, should the Commission use this
method, it could spell disaster for a sizable segment of the hydropower
industry and its electric consumers. Should FERC decide to re-evaluate
its system of determining annual charges based on this report, NHA
recommends that the Commission reject the fair market value/net
benefits approach. NHA also believes Congress should reject the fair
market value analysis underpinning this report.
Based on information disseminated by GAO in meetings with the
hydropower licensees whose 24 hydro projects were studied,
implementation of the "net benefits" methodology would cause huge
increases and huge changes in annual federal land use charges from year
to year. For instance, compared with current charges, the percentage
change, using the GAO "net benefits" methodology, could range from
approximately negative 130,000% to positive 875,000% depending on the
project, market conditions and:
the share of annual net project benefits paid as land use fees. In
fact, based on 2000 market values and project characteristics, the land
use charges for one particular project in the Northwest would skyrocket
from $371,000 to over $602 million a year! This is especially troubling
when one considers that Congress is currently exploring legislative
solutions to prevent unreasonable increases in granted, issued or
renewed rights-of-way fees associated with deployment of
telecommunications and other critical infrastructure on federal lands.
The increased costs resulting from implementation of this GAO
methodology would directly impact ratepayers. In addition, implementing
this methodology would create a new layer of bureaucracy at FERC and
further complicate the hydropower regulatory process. At a time when
FERC is administering the most extensive and complex regulatory process
for any energy source in the United States, it cannot afford to
mobilize the huge effort necessary to implement GAO's complicated
scheme. More importantly, implementing the GAO methodology could
undermine recent administrative and pending legislative reforms to the
hydropower licensing process - valuable reforms that took years to
achieve. It would also undermine incentives for new hydropower
development presently under consideration by Congress.
GAO's draft report to Congress on federal land use fees presents
overwhelming substantive, legal and procedural concerns for the
hydropower industry. Without question, GAO's recommendations would
negatively impact hydropower at a time when policies are being
developed to better integrate hydropower into our national energy
strategy. Again, NHA appreciates the opportunity to comment on this
important matter and hopes our comments will be fully taken into
consideration, and the report revised to address our concerns.
COMMENTS OF THE ASSOCIATION:
I. ECONOMICS:
A. Basing Annual Charges on "Net Benefits" will Result in Unreasonable
Increased Costs to Licensees:
Implementation of the "net benefits" approach used by GAO would greatly
increase the operating costs of many hydro project owners. The sample
of 24 non-federal FERC-licensed hydropower projects, as described in
the draft report, currently pay a cumulative total of approximately
$2.7 million. Under the GAO "net benefits" approach, these same
projects could pay an estimated total of $157.5 million to $1.687
billion per year. These figures could correspond to an annual fee
increase as much as 875,285% for one project alone. [NOTE 2]
Such a significant aggregate fee increase will necessarily be passed
along, to the maximum extent possible, to the electric ratepayers who
use power from the affected projects. Some electric ratepayers could
end up paying as much as 25% more for their electric power without any
additional benefit. At a time when electric industry restructuring is
increasingly introducing competitive electric power markets in various
regions of the country, this has the potential to render hydropower
projects economically uncompetitive compared to other power generation
technologies.
Estimating the effects of the GAO approach raises other significant
economic questions relating to the different types of hydropower
project operators. For example, investor-owned utilities subject to
cost-of-service rate regulation, municipal or other public power
producers, and federal agencies who operate
hydropower facilities all pay taxes infrastructure maintenance and
construction costs differently, and hence, would experience very
different exposure to additional costs under the GAO's approach. This
raises concerns about economic equity among the different types of
hydropower operators in the U.S.
Even if economic equity issues can be addressed, issues of variability
and volatility of economic impacts would still remain. "Net benefits"
will fluctuate from year to year at any given project as costs or
revenues fluctuate. A project that produces zero net revenue, or that
produces a negative net benefit, would be very difficult to handle
fairly under such an approach as the GAO uses. These are very serious
issues which GAO fails to adequately address in its draft report.
B. GAO's Methodology Yields Anomalous Results:
The methodology used by GAO yields anomalous results: for some of the
projects, in some years the calculated "net benefit" is negative, not
positive. For a few projects, the "net benefit" is negative in most
scenarios. GAO attempts to explain this anomaly away, first by pointing
out that the methodology forced a cost-of-capital based on an industry
average return on investment of 7.22 percent, and then by concluding
that negative "net benefits" must reflect a project owner's willingness
to accept a lower-than-average return on investment. GAO further states
that these projects would eventually be abandoned or shut down, if they
are not able to provide a (presumably) competitive return on
investment. Finally, GAO obscures the anomaly by ignoring these
negative values when calculating the total land rents associated with
the 24 projects in the sample used for the report.
There are several problems that are revealed by the appearance of
negative benefits. First, negative benefits would imply that the
landowner (the federal government acting on behalf of national
taxpayers) should receive a less-than-competitive return on its
investment in those years or scenarios that show a negative benefit,
and should make payments to license holders. However, GAO does not
propose that FERC should be provided with funds to actually make
payments to licensees under these circumstances, because such a
proposal would be ludicrous. Rather, GAO proposes that the landowner
should have a preferential interest in the hypothetical "net benefits"
of the projects: the landowner should get a share of these net benefits
when they are positive, but should not share in the "net benefits" when
they are negative.
This thinking undermines the very notion of applying the concept of
"fair market value", because in a real market owners of fixed assets
face the potential of losing money as well as making money. For
example, the owner of a commercial building may face periods of
extremely slack demand, when the building is empty and producing no
revenues, yet the owner still has to pay property taxes and other
operating and maintenance costs. Under these circumstances, the asset
owner receives a "negative net benefit"; in contrast, GAO proposes
special treatment for the federal landowner, assuring that the risks of
ownership are not fully passed on to the landowner.
Second, by excluding these negative "net benefits," GAO overstates the
potential land rents that could be assessed, and gives an
unrealistically optimistic picture of the potential revenues that the
federal landowner could earn. As GAO states, consistent negative "net
benefits" could mean that these projects are eventually shut down or
abandoned. If FERC imposes exorbitant land rents, based on the GAO
methodology, the likelihood of such shut-downs will clearly increase.
If FERC imposes an asymmetric land rent methodology, which increases
costs in good years but does not provide rebates in bad years, the
likelihood of project shut-downs will increase further. Projects that
do not operate will not produce "net benefits" at all, and the federal
landowner will not receive land rents at all.
C. Land Is Not the Only Fixed Factor of Production:
GAO's methodology assumes that land is the only fixed factor of
production (input). This is clearly an erroneous assumption in the
context of this study. Although before the projects were built, land
may have been the only fixed factor, at this point there are many other
fixed inputs, including the hydroelectric structures themselves, in
some cases water rights that have been acquired, many bridges and
roads, fixed hatchery investments and other site improvements, and any
other investments with negligible or even negative salvage value. These
inputs are also fixed, in the sense that they cannot be picked up and
moved to other locations, or put to other economic uses. From this
point on, according to the economic theory applied by GAO, these other
fixed factors, and not just land, should also receive a share of the
"net benefits." In fact, these other fixed factors should receive
shares of the "net benefits" commensurate with the nature of the
investments that have been made and the risks that have been
undertaken. GAO applies its "fixed factor" methodology in a highly
selective manner, which demonstrates a bias toward capturing for the
federal government a highly disproportionate share of the "net
benefits." This cannot be described as an equitable application of the
concept of "fair market value".
D. Only Individual Consumers Will Pay for Higher Land Rents:
GAO attempts to suggest that there may be circumstances in which
shareholders, instead of ratepayers, will end up paying higher land
rents. GAO's logic is flawed; ratepayers are the only source of
revenues for these higher land rents, except in those few, isolated
cases where non-federal hydro projects have already been sold to
private entities. To see this, consider two scenarios: (1) the hydro
projects remain as part of a regulated utility's rate base; and (2) the
hydro projects (in those cases where the licensees are investor-owned
utilities) are sold in the future to a private entity as part of a
divestiture program. In the first scenario, it is clear that higher
land rents will become just another cost of operation, passed along to
consumers.
In the second scenario, now that GAO has put potential buyers on
notice, the prices bid for hydro projects will be reduced to reflect
not only the expected value of the higher land rents, but the
volatility in such rents. Reductions in bid prices will automatically
reduce the "transition credits" received by ratepayers when the hydro
projects are sold to private buyers. That is, the capitalized cost to
the buyer of the stream of future, higher land rents will reduce the
prices offered for the assets in any divestiture
program. Furthermore, higher operating costs in the form of land rents
will under some circumstances increase the market price of energy,
which will also drive up retail rates. The reduced prices paid for
these assets at the time of divestiture, plus the higher costs for
energy after divestiture, mean higher rates for ratepayers. Thus, there
is no scenario, except where hydro projects have already been sold, in
which shareholders would bear any of these additional land rent costs.
GAO's conclusion is flawed, and Congress should understand that the
entire weight of the higher land rents would fall squarely on the backs
of consumers.
E. Rate Impacts in Washington, Oregon and Idaho:
GAO alleges that rates in Washington, Oregon and Idaho are relatively
low, implying that increases in land rent costs will not be a
significant problem. GAO has not recognized the significant increase in
retail electricity rates in the Northwest since the fall of 2001, due
to the West Coast energy crisis of 2000-01. These retail rates are
under continuing upward pressure due to low water conditions in the
region, as well as cost increases at the Bonneville Power
Administration. For some utilities that would be affected directly by
the methodology used by GAO, retail rates are now higher than in many
other parts of the country. In part due to these rate increases,
unemployment and retail shut-offs have increased. Further increases in
retail rates will wreak more havoc on the Northwest economy.
F. GAO Relies on Market Price Indices that Do Not Represent Fair Market
Value:
For hydro projects in the West, GAO calculates "value" by using a
market price index compiled from data associated with transactions at
the California Power Exchange (Cal-PX). There are several problems with
this approach. First, the Cal-PX no longer is in operation, which means
that this market price index is not available. Second, for Northwest
hydro projects, output cannot be sold in California without obtaining
transmission rights, which are not available on a year-round basis due
to previous commitments by transmission owners. Third, even when
transmission capacity is available, it is not free. Thus, the Cal-PX
index is inappropriate for Northwest hydro projects.
Most importantly, GAO seeks to determine fair market value, but has not
evaluated whether this particular index, or any other index, in fact
reflects the "fair market value" of the generation. If there is
manipulation of the markets that produce these indices, as FERC has
recently concluded, then the resulting prices themselves do not
represent fair market value, but rather reflect market manipulation. By
relying on manipulated price indices, GAO's methodology could produce a
windfall profit for the federal landowner.
II. PRACTICALITY AND LOGISTICS:
The GAO methodology to determine the "net benefits" for use in
assessing federal land use charges at FERC-licensed hydropower projects
would create an unprecedented administrative burden and additional
reporting requirements and accounting measures for both the FERC and
licensees. The current system is efficient and poses reasonable
administrative requirements on both the licensee and FERC. More or
less, FERC has two staff personnel assigned part time to the work
associated with all annual charges under Section 10(e) of the Federal
Power Act (FPA). Adopting the GAO methodology would certainly require a
major transfer in FERC personnel and resources to handle the workload
required on a yearly basis to manage the new program. Likewise, the
current system poses a reasonable burden on licensees in terms of
record keeping and reporting requirements. The GAO "net benefits"
approach, however, would represent an enormous and unnecessary
administrative burden on licensees and FERC.
To illustrate some of the questions and difficulties that would arise
with implementation of the highly complex "net benefits" approach used
by GAO, it's important to look at some of the critical elements that
are part and parcel to such a methodology. Basically, it will be
impossible to generalize any of the input parameters for a "net
benefits" determination for all licensees because each licensee and
each project will have distinct financial, operational and maintenance
criteria, and the most likely form of alternative generation for
comparison purposes will vary significantly from region to region.
For instance, the cost of money for public and private owners of
hydropower projects varies according to the type of entity (i.e. state,
county, public utility district, irrigation district, cooperative,
private utility, industrial company, private entrepreneur, etc). The
financing rate for funds varies dramatically for public agencies and
other public non-profit entities. Likewise, private companies usually
finance in a variety of approaches using a combination of debt and
equity that can differ significantly from company to company. In
addition, the cost of funds can and does change significantly from year
to year. Therefore, this would require each licensee to develop and
provide extensive financial data for each annual charge calculation.
In addition, the operation and maintenance (O&M) costs for hydropower
projects vary significantly, and are influenced by age, physical
location, climate, and many other factors. Therefore, O&M costs
fluctuate from project to project and for each individual project from
year-to-year. There simply is no general information that would provide
an accurate O&M cost for a hydropower project. Each licensee would need
to furnish such information on an annual basis.
The value of power from the most likely alternative generating source,
a critical input to the GAO's "net benefits" determination, will also
change annually due to fuel costs, O&M costs, location, and
availability factors. Hydropower projects located in the same area will
have substantially different alternative power values based on the
source for the alternative that is unique to each licensee, thus
creating controversy, and, ultimately, inequities. In some cases there
are no alternatives other than hydropower, creating a serious problem
in determining one's fees if this aspect of the method is employed.
Furthermore, the GAO methodology does not address the numerous
inequities that will occur. For instance, there is no recognition of
the entrepreneurial activity associated with constructing the primary
facilities that create the value in a hydropower project, namely the
dam and power generating and transmission facilities. These major
elements of a hydropower project typically represent more than 95% of a
project's total cost. Land associated with a hydropower facility
represents 5 % or less of the total cost of a hydropower facility in
many cases. However, the GAO application of the "net benefits" approach
assumes that all the "net benefits" accrue to only the lands, so that
for a project located entirely on federal land, up to 100 % of the "net
benefits" could be assessed as the annual lands charge, thereby giving
no credit for the investment in the important facilities that created
the actual benefit. These and other inequities will inevitably result
in disputes and litigation.
Federal lands are included within FERC project boundaries for a variety
of reasons. Lands devoted to power generation vary significantly and in
some cases represent a small portion of the lands subject to annual
charges. Large tracts of lands are included for non-power purposes that
serve environmental, recreation, and other purposes. Licensees receive
no income or value from these lands, yet are charged for their use as
part of the FERC project license fees. In addition, the public receives
benefits from these other purposes, and thus is already compensated for
the use of federal lands by licensed hydropower projects. GAO's
methodology completely ignores these other benefits. Furthermore,
projects located in the same general area on federal land, and that
should have the same approximate value, will have substantially
different "net benefits" in light of the different alternative power
values, financial costs, O&M and other factors cited above.
Finally, if the GAO methodology is adopted, as stated above, it will be
necessary for each licensee to submit on an annual basis extensive
financial information, O&M costs, alternative power values, and other
information to FERC. With respect to FERC, the agency would need to:
* Implement significant changes in its billing system,
* Conduct over 300 separate "net benefits" analyses every year,
* Make substantial revisions to its efficient computer-driven billing
system to account for the variability of its annual charges billings,
* Substantially increase its staff and resources to process and gather
the necessary information to perform the time-consuming "net benefits"
analyses, and:
* Process complaints, disputes, or litigation associated with the annual
charge analyses.
In summary, the GAO methodology, if adopted, will create an entirely
new system with extensive record keeping and reporting requirements
that will substantially increase the administrative burden on FERC and
the hydropower industry. What's more, the GAO methodology will be
inherently unpredictable and inefficient, problems that the current
system was designed to avoid. Disputes regarding computations, data,
inequities, and other problems will inevitably result in complaints,
disputes, or substantial and prolonged litigation.
III. LEGAL IMPLICATIONS:
A. The GAO Methodology is Inconsistent with the Federal Power Act,
Because Fair Market Value is Not a Basis for a Reasonable Fee:
FERC's authority to impose annual charges upon licensees comes from the
Federal Power Act, Section 10(e), which, in relevant part, provides:
"That the licensee shall pay to the United States reasonable annual
charges in an amount to be fixed by the Commission for the purpose of
reimbursing the United States for the costs of the administration of
this Part; for recompensing it for the use, occupancy and enjoyment of
its lands or other property; ... and in fixing such charges the
Commission shall seek to avoid increasing the price to the consumers of
power by such charges, and any such charges may be adjusted from time
to time by the Commission as conditions may require: ...":
Section 10(e) goes on to provide that reasonable annual fees for the
use of tribal lands and government dams will also be imposed by FERC.
However, those fees are subject to approval by the Secretary of the
Interior for dams in reclamation projects and by the Indian tribe for
tribal lands.
Fair market value is not a reasonable fee. The GAO indicates the "net
benefits" method is designed to obtain fair market value for the use of
federal lands by a licensee. However, the FPA § 10(e) requirement for
land fees is not tied to fair market value. In fact, fair market value
is a greater value than the "reasonable annual charge" set out in FPA §
10(e). In City of Vanceburg v. FERC, the Court of Appeals considered
the question of whether FPA § 10(e) charges for the use of a
governmental dam were reasonable. The court reasoned:
"[T]he Commission must set a reasonable charge by considering all
relevant factors and arriving at a charge which minimizes consumer
costs, encourages power development, but at the same time, compensates
the Government to some extent for the benefit it has conferred on the
licensee." [NOTE 3]
In upholding the fee, the court indicated that FERC must consider a
number of different factors in setting the fee, including factors that
would necessarily result in a fee below the "fair market value" of the
federal land. For example, if FERC were to always focus on a fee that
met the fair market value of the federal land, the Commission would
fail to take into account the FPA § 10(e) direction to "seek to avoid
increasing the price" of power to consumers. FPA § 10(e) does not
promote a fair market value standard. In fact, the court in City of
Vanceburg also stated:
"[W]e do not suggest that the Commission is free automatically to
assess as charges the full amount of the value conferred on a
licensee." [NOTE 4]
In the draft report, GAO recognizes the Federal Power Act's requirement
that FERC balance competing interests in setting its fees. However, the
use of fair market value and the "net benefits" analysis installs a
baseline that is unreasonable from the start. Although GAO does not
recommend that a certain percentage of the "net benefits" from a
project go to the United States, the report points out that FERC has
frequently used a 50150 split to determine the benefits from the
licensee's use of tribal land and the use of a government dam. Further,
even if FERC were to use a smaller percentage in determining the amount
of the annual charge for federal land, the GAO formula is still based
on determining the value of the land
through the determination of the "net benefits" obtained by the
licensee through the operation of the hydro project.
B. The Annual Fee for Federal Lands Must Be Calculated Differently From
the Fee for Use of a Government Dam:
Although the annual fee for the use of federal lands will compensate
the United States for the benefit conferred upon the licensee, the
reasonable fee amount should not be calculated in the same manner as
the fee for the use of a government dam. The Vanceburg court explained
that a national average rental value is appropriate to compensate the
government for the use of federal lands, which is the benefit derived
from a "fungible tract of real estate".' The use of water at a specific
government owned dam provides a much larger benefit upon the licensee
because the licensee need not construct or operate the dam.
In the case of federal land, the land could be, and generally is, used
for authorized purposes (other than hydropower). Also, the licensee
must construct, operate, and maintain all the necessary project works.
Thus, the benefit conferred upon the licensee by the use of federal
land is fundamentally different. However, the "net benefits" method
would treat the use of federal land similarly to the use of a
government dam.
Moreover, the compensation method for the use of government dams has
significantly changed - now requiring a graduated charge in mills per
kilowatt-hour based upon the amount of energy provided. 18 C.F.R. §
11.3. Using the "net benefits" approach for government lands could
result in a higher fee paid by users of federal lands than users of
government dams.
C. The Use of a Royalty Type Fee is Inappropriate:
FPA Section 10(e) is not "intended to be a general revenue raising
statute". [NOTE 6] When previously addressing the appropriate method
for calculating annual charges, FERC concurred with this conclusion
and determined:
"that a percentage of gross sales fee or a flat rate per kilowatt hour
fee is not a reasonable method of assessing land use charges. The
tiered system suggested by the Forest Service is also unreasonable, as
it would charge a royalty for run-of-river projects as though the
Federal land being used was producing the power. This overlooks the
fact that many projects use a combination of federal and private lands,
and that the power output is a result of many factors (water rights,
head, project structure) and not just the acreage of federal land
involved." [NOTE 7]
The GAO analysis contains the very defects that caused FERC to dismiss
similar valuation methods in the past. Moreover, the GAO method assumes
that the federal lands contribute equal value to a hydro project's
ability to generate power compared to the other private lands upon
which the project is located. Unlike the use of a government dam, which
directly enables a hydro project to divert water and generate power,
the use of federal lands may or may not provide that benefit. FERC
would need to conduct a case-by-case analysis of each hydro project to
determine the value provided by the use of the federal lands. The GAO
method does not propose such a case-by-case approach and its arbitrary
division of value based upon the acreage of federal land occupied is
inappropriate.
D. The Sharing of the "Net Benefits" Method Does Not Accurately Consider
the Actual Value of the Property:
Importantly, determining the value of the federal lands used by the
licensee should not be tied to the generation benefits that will be
derived from the project. The benefits conferred upon the licensee by
the land should be no different from the benefits conferred upon any
other user of that federal land. The federal land's value is the value
of its "highest and best use". This entails determining the "highest
and best use" of the land at the time it was acquired or, at most, its
likely use in the reasonably near future. [NOTE 8] This value may be
established by the use of comparable sales, or the average rental
values of comparable lands. Court decisions dealing with the
condemnation of land for hydro projects have reached this same
conclusion. In Public District No. 1 v. City of Seattle, 382 F.2d 666,
673 (9th Cir. 1967), the court stated:
"Power value may generally be said to be of two types. First, there is
the value increment which one engaged in the assembling of lands needed
for a power project would be willing to pay in order to include such
land in its needed package. Such values typically are established by
proof of comparable sales." (emphasis added).
The court went on to conclude that the profit that could be achieved
from a power project was not an appropriate valuation method because it
assumed that the property would be put to use as a hydroelectric
project by the federal government in the near future. Id. The FERC
would not have licensed a hydro project to a private party if the
United States had plans to construct the hydro project. Consequently,
the federal government may not now argue that hydropower was the
highest and best use of the project. Assuming the federal land had
value as a power generation source is not a valid method for
calculating the annual charge for the use of the federal land.
Instead, the GAO report should consider the process by which the
federal government determines the amount of compensation it would pay
for private land acquisition. These federal acquisition guidelines
require the use of comparable sales. [NOTE 9] It also notes that the
preferred way to appraise a leasehold estate is to use comparable lease
transactions. [NOTE 10] The FERC licenses are roughly equivalent to a
land lease. Therefore, the value of the federal lands should be
determined based upon the highest and best use of the lands before the
lands were withdrawn for power purposes pursuant to FPA Section 24.
If the United States desires to obtain the power generation value of
the federal lands, the FPA provides a mechanism to achieve that goal.
FPA Sections 14 and 15 allow the United States to takeover a
hydroelectric project at the end of the current license term. Allowing
the federal government to impose the charges contemplated by the
sharing of the "net benefits" method essentially gives the government
50 percent of the generation benefits created by a hydroelectric
project without assuming any of the hydro project's risks and without
compensating the licensee for this "taking." In other words, the GAO
method gives the government over one-half the benefits envisioned by a
take-over without the accompanying FPA responsibilities.
F. The GAO Method will Result in Significant Increases in Costs That
Will Be Reflected in Electric Rates:
The GAO method, if adopted by FERC, would admittedly result in
increased annual charges paid by hydro project licensees. These costs
must be accounted for in some fashion. Most municipal hydro
project owners and the majority of public utilities continue to pass
through their hydro operation and maintenance costs along to their
customers. This applies to private utilities as well. The increased
charges for the use of federal lands will then cause consumer prices
for electricity to increase. FPA Section 10(e) clearly instructs the
Commission to avoid price increases to consumers.
IV. PUBLIC POLICY IMPLICATIONS:
There are several public policy implications tied directly to FERC's
potential use of the GAO methodology for determining fair market value
for use of federal lands in assessing annual charges. The most notable
are:
* a massive failure to adequately recognize the many valuable benefits
our nation's leading renewable resource offers the American public;
* the creation of yet another barrier to further developing this
underutilized but indispensable energy resource;
* the loss of hydropower generation and an increase in pollution from
less clean alternate energy sources; and:
* an increase in electricity costs.
A. GAO's Methodology Ignores or Fails to Capture the Many Benefits of
Hydropower:
Hydropower offers the American public a tremendous number of valuable
benefits. These benefits include, but are not limited to, low cost and
pollution-free power supply, transmission system reliability, energy
security, flood control, water supply, recreation and irrigation. In
addition, projects licensed by FERC contribute to improved
environmental and natural resource quality through protection,
mitigation and enhancement measures conducted by licensees on their own
or through license conditions issued by FERC. The industry has spent
hundreds of millions, if not billions, of dollars enhancing the
environment and providing recreation and other benefits for the
American public.
One of the presumptions of GAO's report is that the federal government
and the American taxpayer is coming up short due to today's system to
collect federal land use fees. On the contrary - the American public
and the taxpayer are gaining numerous invaluable benefits from use of
federal land for hydropower production. In its attempt to capture fair
market value, GAO's methodology largely ignores or inaccurately
captures these very important benefits when calculating the project's
"net benefits." GAO's methodology does not consider what the American
public gains when federal lands are used by hydropower owners and
operators, whether these benefits where created by actions of the
licensee, directed by FERC or federal resource agencies, or occur
naturally as a result of using America's rivers to generate clean
electricity. The GAO methodology instead focuses solely on the project
owners' financial or "special benefits" - what the owners and operators
are gaining financially for use of federal land to generate
electricity.
When issuing licenses, however, FERC weighs all interests and adopts
license terms and conditions to achieve a project that is well-suited
to a comprehensive plan for the waterway. It does not focus solely on
economics, as GAO does in its draft report. One of the ways in which
the Commission achieves a balanced project is by requiring licensees to
pay annual charges. The payment of annual charges is not a separate and
distinct feature of the FPA. It is only one aspect of an overall
framework of developing hydropower facilities that meet many public
uses. Similarly, potential federal land use fees should be adjusted to
recognize the public benefits provided by the projects, such as
recreation, flood control, irrigation, navigation, water supply, fish
and wildlife enhancement, etc. The current system for collecting
land use fees captures these benefits and recognizes the value to the
American public of using federal lands for hydropower generation. GAO's
methodology, however, does not.
The "net benefits" approach used by GAO does not account for these
public benefits in all instances. For example, the net benefit
methodology calculates, for each project, the cost of generating
hydropower. This calculation may account for some public benefits
provided by the project, such as operation and maintenance costs for
recreational facilities. However, many of the more costly license terms
that reduce production at the facilities would not be included in any
cost calculation.
For instance, many license conditions require the licensee to forego
the use of some of its water to provide for in stream flows for
whitewater rafting and fisheries enhancement. Other license conditions
establish minimum and/or maximum reservoir levels to provide for
recreation, flood control, and/or fisheries. All of these license
conditions constrain the ability of licensees to operate their projects
at a higher capacity. Yet, FERC Form 1 and EIA Form EIA-412, which GAO
uses in its net benefit methodology, are not sufficiently sensitive to
these concerns to yield useable and reliable data necessary to make
these calculations. Because such constraints would not be included in
the "net benefits" calculation, the methodology does not capture the
expense associated with these public benefits.
In addition, FERC recognizes that hydropower projects possess benefits
not present in fossil sources of generation. Many hydro projects serve
peak loads and provide valuable ancillary services due to the unique
nature of hydropower generation and its ability to dispatch electricity
quickly. This is not the case for all facilities, however, as some
plants are non-dispatchable or run-of-river facilities. Other
methodologies could take these unique factors into account, but GAO's
methodology fails to do so, again highlighting the inadequacy of the
analysis and its inability to capture hydro's benefits.
Congress and the administration have been working to devise hydropower
policies that better recognize, and better balance, our nation's energy
needs and important environmental goals. Significant progress has
recently been made on these fronts through legislative and
administrative improvements in the hydropower licensing process. In
addition, Congress is considering incentives to tap into the large
amount of unused hydro capacity in the U.S. Adopting the GAO "net
benefits" recommendation would amount to nothing less than a
significant step backwards in recognizing and valuing the contributions
of our nation's hydropower resources in meeting our energy and
environmental policies. By failing to capture or accurately recognize
the many contributions hydropower makes to clean air, a sustainable
future and a higher quality of life for American citizens, the GAO
methodology fails to serve the American public and would jeopardize
progress made on critical hydropower issues of late. It is a major flaw
that cannot be overlooked.
B. Adoption of the Methodology Would Discourage Hydropower Development:
The GAO's "net benefits" methodology also discourages hydropower
development, an already underutilized resource. FERC and the courts
have long found that one of the main purposes of the FPA is to
encourage hydropower development. One of the primary mechanisms to
encourage development is for FERC to issue licenses with fixed terms
sufficient to make the licensee secure in its investment. The FPA
itself precludes unilateral changes to license terms and conditions by
FERC or Congress. Even upon expiration of a license, FERC cannot simply
change license terms in the new license without providing reasoned
explanation.
To comply with this underling policy of the FPA, the Commission has
chosen a straightforward, transparent means to calculate its federal
land-use rents and has specifically rejected a more complex, cost-based
system. In fact, FERC has previously rejected the "net benefits"
approach on the basis that it would not serve the goal of encouraging
hydroelectric development. In changing its methodology for
collecting fees for the use of government dams from a "net benefits"
approach to a flat rate approach, the Commission found that the flat
rate approach:
"is relatively simple and straightforward both for the Commission to
administer and for potential developers to factor into their project
feasibility studies. This will enhance the certainty of hydro project
development ...A flat rate method does not require the complex
calculations inherent in the generic [net benefits] method ... This
complexity would interfere unnecessarily with the Commission's need for
administrative workability and licensees' need for predictability.":
Because the "net benefits" approach calculates a charge using data
points that would likely fluctuate from year-to-year, its use would
conflict with policies of the FPA that require certainty and
predictability regarding licensees' obligations under the terms of
their licenses. Considering the volatility of the electric market from
year-to-year, the uncertainty of these costs would interfere with
prudent utility management and long-term planning and budgeting.
Certainly, this effect would be inconsistent with the broad policy of
the FPA to encourage hydroelectric development.
NHA forecasts that 21.3 Gigawatts (GWs) of additional power from
hydroelectric resources could be developed by 2020 - none of which
would require the construction of a new dam or impoundment. In terms of
greenhouse gas reductions, this would equal displacing 24 million
metric tons of carbon emissions. Of the 21.3 GWs, over 4,300 MWs of
"incremental hydropower" could be developed, meeting today's
environmental standards at existing hydropower facilities through
capacity additions and efficiency improvements. This is enough power
for approximately four million homes - clearly a significant
contribution to our nation's energy supply. Adoption of GAO's
methodology would undermine attempts to develop this great renewable
potential.
At a time when the administration and Congress are designing policies
to increase our usage of domestic energy resources, including
hydropower, policy analyses, such as GAO's, would discourage and
seriously undermine our ability to tap into unused hydropower capacity,
should be strongly discouraged and rejected. GAO's approach to land use
fees is inconsistent with the administration's National Energy Policy
and Congress's intent as it debates a comprehensive national energy
policy. What's more, the American public has spoken to the issue of
encouraging additional hydropower development - 74% of registered
voters support incentives from the federal government to further
develop our existing hydropower infrastructure. [NOTE 11] As Congress,
the White House and the American public have realized, we need to
encourage additional hydropower development. GAO's "net benefits"
methodology does just the opposite, and that is a shortsighted and
ill-advised policy to pursue.
C. GAO's Methodology Could Lead to the Loss of Hydropower Generation and
an Increase in Pollution and Electricity Costs:
Adoption of the "net benefits" approach could also lead to the loss of
hydropower generation and an increase in pollution and higher-priced
electricity. As we outlined earlier in our comments, the financial
impacts of the "net benefits" approach could be devastating for certain
hydropower projects. If adoption of this methodology led to the shut
down of hydropower facilities or a significant loss of clean megawatts,
those facilities and its megawatts would likely be replaced with
natural gas-fired or fossil power plants that emit greenhouse gases and
would cost more in terms of electricity prices. Pursuing a policy that
would create such a scenario is irresponsible, at best. The American
public should be faced with neither of these choices - more pollution
or higher electricity prices. At a time when air pollution,
greenhouse gases and electricity prices are of major concern, we should
pursue policies which remedy these concerns, not exacerbate them, as
the GAO "net benefits" methodology would surely do.
D. GAO's Methodology Would Require Congressional Action and a Major
Shift in Energy Policy:
Congress specifically structured the FPA not to require the collection
of the full "fair market value" of federal lands used for energy
production. Instead, the FPA is intended to meet policy goals other
than recouping the United States for the full "fair market value" of
its lands. As discussed above, the FPA is intended to encourage
efficient administration, encourage hydropower development, ensure
low-cost rates to consumers, and consolidate all hydropower regulatory
authority in FERC. FERC's current system of collecting federal land-use
rents is firmly rooted in all these policies.
Of course, Congress could implement changes, but even a seemingly
simple amendment to require the collection of Federal land-use rents at
"fair market value" would require a fundamental shift in policy.
Indeed, under the FPA, Congress did not intend FERC to collect these
charges at full "fair market value." When Congress desires an agency to
recover land use fees at "fair market value," it specifically provides
for such recovery. For example, many Federal statutes - such as the
Federal Land Policy and Management Act, the Mineral Leasing Act, and
the National Forest Ski Area Permit Act of 1986 - specifically require
Federal agencies to recover "fair market value" for the use of Federal
lands. However, Congress may dictate a standard other than full "fair
market value," as it has done in the Federal Power Act. In fact, the
Office of Management and Budget's ("OMB") Circular No. A-25, which
implements Title V of the Independent Offices Appropriation Act of
1952, recognizes that Congress may establish a standard upon which to
collect user fees other than full "fair market value." The GAO has even
recognized in the subject report that a standard other than full "fair
market value" may apply to federal land-use rents.
Indeed, Congress often requires standards other than the full "fair
market value." For example, the Land and Water Conservation Fund Act
requires land-use rental charges to be "fair and equitable." Similarly,
the Taylor Grazing Act of 1934 requires holders of grazing permits to
pay "annual reasonable fees." The same holds true for the FPA. In
establishing cost recovery for the use of federal lands under the FPA,
Congress specifically chose standards other than "fair market value.":
Section 10(e)(1) of the FPA provides for licensees to "pay to the
United States reasonable annual charges ... for recompensing it for the
use, occupancy, and enjoyment of its lands or other property..."
Moreover, Section 10(e)(1) also sets the standard that "in fixing such
charges the Commission shall seek to avoid increasing the price to the
consumers of power by such charges..." Together, these standards in
Section 10(e)(1) establish that Congress intended for the Commission
not to collect in annual charges the full "fair market rental value" of
Federal lands. As explained by the Court of Appeals for the District of
Columbia Circuit:
"[W]e do not suggest that the Commission is free automatically to
assess as charges the full amount of the value conferred on a licensee.
. . [T]he Commission must set a reasonable charge by considering all
relevant factors and arriving at a charge which minimizes consumer
costs, encourages power development, but at the same time, compensates
the Government to some extent for the benefit it has conferred on the
licensee.":
Thus, Section 10(e)(1) embodies the fundamental policies of the FPA,
such as encouraging hydropower development and ensuring low-cost power
to consumers. If Congress were to determine that these policies should
give way to an overriding policy that favors full recovery of federal
land-use rents, it would have to specifically authorize FERC to collect
federal land-use rents at fair market value. This
would mark a major shift in policy that has been recognized and pursued
for over 80 years. What's more, it would directly conflict with current
efforts by Congress to devise legislative solutions to prevent
unreasonable increases in granted, issued or renewed rights-of-way fees
associated with deployment of telecommunications and other critical
infrastructure on federal lands. This would force Congress into
pursuing two very different paths with regard to land use and rights-
of-way fees paid by various industries.
V. CONSISTENCY WITH SOUND ACCOUNTING PRACTICE:
It is important that the underlying accounting philosophy used by the
GAO be sound. First, it is desirable to provide equitable compensation
for the land owner. Second, it is important that land use fees are
determined in a way that does not distort the economics of existing
projects or potential future projects. If land use fees are
inappropriately high, the development of new projects and the expansion
of existing economical, renewable energy projects would be discouraged.
The GAO methodology does not correctly allocate the benefits of the
project. When accounting for the value of land that is developed for
its natural resources, there are generally three components that must
be included: 1) acquisition, 2) exploration, and 3) development. By
essentially prorating the value of the project on the basis of land
ownership only, the GAO methodology ignores that substantial
contributions have been made to the value of the land by development of
the project and project improvements. If benefits of the project are to
be allocated to the various capital components, then value should not
be assigned solely to the land but should be further allocated among
the other capital contributions. Further, beyond the need to recognize
the contributions from capital, there must be recognition of and return
provided for entrepreneurial risk. To illustrate the problems with the
GAO methodology, consider the case at the extreme where 100% of project
land is federally owned. The GAO methodology would not provide for
allocation of any benefits to exploration and development, nor to
entrepreneurial risk, nor to any other fixed investments that have been
made in the projects.
Conflicts between the GAO methodology and sound appraisal practices are
discussed elsewhere, but it should be noted that the GAO methodology is
in conflict with accounting valuation practices as well as appraisal
practices. Land value is most often established for accounting purposes
based on historical cost, but other means of valuation are used. An
alternative, fair market value (defined as what is given up to acquire
the land or its own fair market value) is more consistent with current
methodologies than the GAO methodology.
VI. CONSISTENCY WITH SOUND APPRAISAL PRACTICE:
A. Present Methodology Used for Valuing Federal Hydro Land:
In order to better understand the inconsistency between the "net
benefits" methodology and established appraisal practice, it is
important to understand the current method being used. In 1987, FERC
adopted its current methodology of using a published United States
Forest Service index of values of transmission rights of way in order
to determine the annual charges for use of federal land on FERC-
licensed hydroelectric projects under Section 10(e) of the Federal
Power Act.
The Forest Service fee schedule is based upon a survey of market values
for the various types of land that the Forest Service has allowed to be
occupied by linear rights of way. [NOTE 12] The schedule is divided
into regional zones and provides per-acre rental fees by state and
county. These fees are arrived at by
multiplying the raw value of the land in each zone by an unspecified
rate-of-return. [NOTE 13] The rates are adjusted downward to reflect
the value difference between rights-of-way authorization granted by
private landowners and those issued by the government. Because of
encumbrances on federal land, it was valued approximately 70 percent
less than similarly situated private land. The result is an annual fee
per-acre per-year for lands used for electric transmission lines; the
fees range from $2.24 for land in Nevada to $44.87 a year for land in
some counties in Florida. [NOTE 14]
Because the Forest Service index is a rate
for charges for transmission rights of way, the Commission doubled the
fees in the index in order to derive a charge for project lands,
explaining "transmission line rights-of-way will be assessed at the
Forest Service index rate and other project land will be assessed at
twice that rate." [NOTE 15] This doubling of the fee schedule reflects
the reduced residual utility of forestland devoted to hydroelectric
project use as opposed to transmission corridor use.
In essence, the FERC's present methodology is based upon "across the
fence" values. The use of an "across the fence" methodology captures
the values of land with similar characteristics to the land being
valued, and appraisers throughout the country routinely rely upon it
because it establishes a value of land based upon comparable sales.
Because the value of the subject land is based upon sales of other like
pieces of land, the FERC present methodology correctly calculates
rental fees based on the value of the land being used.
B. A History of Methodologies Used to Value Federal Property Used in
Hydroelectric Projects:
It is also important to understand the history of past methodologies
when considering revisions. Since 1938, the Commission has established
fees for hydroelectric licensees' use of federal land using various
methodologies. From 1938 until 1942, the Commission based the fees on a
project-by-project basis. This method proved to be uneconomic because
of the excessive costs of the appraisal in comparison to the value of
the land involved. Consequently, in 1942 the Commission developed a
national average value of $50 an acre, and recognizing that the Federal
land was being used rather than purchased, approximated a rental value
by selecting an interest rate as a rate of return that could be
multiplied by the value of the land to determine a fee. The Commission
chose an interest rate of four percent, thereby deriving a rental rate
of $2.00 per acre. Twenty years later, in 1962, the Commission
increased the average value per acre of federal land to $60 but
retained the four percent interest rate, thereby increasing the annual
land use charge to $2.40 per acre. Then, in 1976, in Order No. 560, 56
F.P.C. 3860, the Commission increased the national average value to
$150 per acre and adopted a fluctuating interest rate used by the
United States Water Resources Council which was based on the average
yield of long-term (15 or more years to maturity) United States
interest-bearing securities.
In 1986, the Commission abandoned its traditional methodology of
multiplying a national average per-acre land value by a rate of return
as the basis for calculating the fees in favor of the Forest Service
fee schedule discussed above. [NOTE 16] In doing so, the Commission
analyzed and rejected various proposed
methodologies, including a charge assessed on a per-kilowatt-hour
basis. The rejected per-kWh hour approach determined the fee by looking
to the generating capability of the entire property-the land and the
facilities on the land. Specifically, the methodology used by GAO
determined the total income that the entire property could generate and
assigned a percentage of that income to the land as rent. Consequently,
the fee would have been based upon the income generating capacity of
the particular property and not the value of the land itself. In its
rejection of this income-based approach, the Commission stated that it
--:
"[A]grees with most of the comments that a percentage of gross sales
fee or a flat rate per kilowatt hour fee is not a reasonable method of
assessing land use charges. The tiered system suggested by the Forest
Service is also unreasonable, as it would charge a royalty for run-of-
river projects as though the Federal land being used was producing the
power. This overlooks the fact that many projects use a combination of
Federal and private lands, and that the power output is a result of
many factors (water rights, head, project structure) and not just the
acreage of Federal land involved. For these reasons the Commission
decides not to adopt the above fee methodologies as a means of
assessing land charges." 52 Fed. Reg. at 18,203. [NOTE 17]
C. Accepted Appraisal Practice:
The GAO methodology conflicts with the Uniform Standards of
Professional Appraisal Practice (USPAP) as established by the Appraisal
Foundation. These standards were mandated by Congress and are the most
authoritative text in the valuation of real estate and are the
generally accepted standards for professional appraisal practice in
North America. USPAP contains standards for all types of appraisal
services. Standards are included for real estate, personal property,
business and mass appraisal. The preparation of USPAP standards is
overseen by the Justice Department and these are the standards required
for most federal land transactions.
USPAP was originally written in 1986-1987 by an appraisal profession Ad
Hoc Committee on Uniform Standards and was donated to The Appraisal
Foundation in 1987. The Financial Institutions Reform, Recovery and
Enforcement Act (FIRREA) of 1989 cites USPAP as the standards to be
enforced by state real estate appraiser licensing agencies. USPAP
compliance is also required by professional appraisal associations,
client groups and by dozens of federal, state and local agencies. It
contains the Standards of Practice for all appraisal disciplines (real
estate, personal property, business and mass appraisal).
USPAP is released on an annual basis. Regulators base enforcement
decisions on the edition of USPAP in effect as of the date of an
appraisal report. It is enforced by regulatory agencies, professional
appraisal associations and client groups; and is growing in acceptance
throughout the world. Many professional associations in Central and
South America, Europe and Asia have accepted and adopted USPAP as the
standard of practice for their membership.
USPAP notes that the methodology to be used when determining the value
of a subject property varies depending on the type of property being
appraised. For example, when determining the value of a facility that
includes both real and personal property, such as a hydroelectric
facility, the appraiser would consider all three approaches to value:
the income approach, the sales comparison approach, and the cost
approach. When using the income approach, the appraiser does not
attempt to separate out the value of land from the other assets being
appraised; instead, the facility is valued as an income-producing unit.
Similarly, when conducting a comparable sales analysis for the
facility, the appraiser compares sales of comparable facilities and
does not separate out the value of the land.
On the other hand, when determining the value of an individual piece of
real estate, such as land to be included within the boundaries of a
hydroelectric project, an appraiser typically determines value by
examining comparable sales of parcels of land with identical or similar
physical characteristics. Thus, the value of the subject property, the
land, is based upon sales of comparable property. This is the approach
recommended in appraisal texts and courses. The appraiser would not,
utilizing accepted appraisal theory and practice, attempt to calculate
the value of the real estate by using an approach that values the
entire facility.
The GAO "net benefits" methodology appears to violate USPAP. In
Standard 1: Real Property Appraisal, Development, Standards Rule 1-4
states that "an appraiser must: develop an opinion of site value by an
appropriate appraisal method or technique." Here, the "net benefits"
methodology values the land by looking at the income producing
potential of the entire project and assigning a portion of the income
value to the real estate. As explained above, the GAO methodology does
not appear to be an appropriate appraisal method or technique to
develop a site value. USPAP identifies the sales comparison approach as
the most appropriate approach when determining the value of land.
Further, Standards Rule 1-1 states that "In developing a real property
appraisal, an appraiser must: be aware of, understand, and correctly
employ those recognized methods and techniques that are necessary to
produce a credible appraisal; not commit a substantial error of
omission or commission that significantly affects an appraisal; and not
render appraisal services in a careless or negligent manner...". The
Uniform Appraisal Standards for Federal Land Acquisitions, a document
prepared for appraisers to utilize in preparing valuations for
acquiring agencies on behalf of the United States, quotes case law,
stating "historically, the capitalization of income approach to value
has been suspect." [NOTE 18] Using the income capitalization approach
requires appraisers to use "...a myriad of factors and variables, the
accuracy of which cannot clearly and easily be demonstrated by market
data". The "net benefits" approach is admittedly uniquely different
from similar methods used in Canada to value hydroelectric projects
(Canada capitalizes the "net benefits" over the life of the project -
not each year). If the FERC projects are valued each year with the
knowledge of the Canadian process using the life of the project as
well as previously approved processes, the resulting valuations could
be deemed to have been performed in a careless and negligent manner.
This "variant" of the Income Capitalization Approach would not use the
actual income produced from the hydroelectric projects. Instead, it
would use market prices of the hydropower produced by the projects to
assign a market value to the land. These market prices will greatly
fluctuate each year, be subject to uncontrollable market manipulations
(as seen in California in 2000) and would not be a proper basis to
determine a project's market value. Again, the Uniform Appraisal
Standards for Federal Land Acquisitions notes that conjectural and
speculative evidence of market value should not be considered.
D. Federal Appraisal Practices:
The purpose of Title XI SEC. 1101.of FIRREA [12 U.S.C. 3331] is to
provide that Federal financial and public policy interests in real
estate related transactions will be protected by requiring that real
estate appraisals utilized in connection with federally related
transactions are performed in writing, in accordance with uniform
standards, by individuals whose competency has been demonstrated and
whose
professional conduct will be subject to effective supervision. Most
Federal real estate transactions should be carried out in accordance
with the standards set by USPAP. As discussed above the "net benefits"
approach is not consistent with the requirements of USPAP and its
implementation will set conflicting standards for Federal Government
transactions.
The "net benefits" methodology is flawed. Its application would very
likely lead to varying and arbitrary federal land use charges. Its
application would be in conflict with the direction Congress has
established under PURPA for the consistent application of Federal real
estate transactions. This variation of land rents would not be related
to the value of the land itself but, rather, on a variety of other
factors. The current methodology is a well-recognized valuation
methodology and does not violate appraisal theory or application. The
value of the land is based upon the value of similar or comparable
land. In addition, the current fee-schedule methodology accounts for
the fact that Federal land is encumbered in a manner that private land
is not, and therefore, has a lower value.
Moreover, if the licensee were able to purchase or condemn the federal
land on which the project is located, it would most likely do so, and
the resulting "just compensation" owed would be the upper limit of the
value of the land. Because federal land is not subject to condemnation,
however, the licensee is, in a sense, held hostage by the federal
government. Application of the "net benefits" methodology would cause
some licensees to pay rents substantially higher than what would be
owed to a private landowner notwithstanding that the federal land is
likely worth less than comparable private land because of governmental
regulations and restrictions.
VII. CONCLUSION:
Though the GAO, in its draft report, does not recommend a particular
formula for assessing federal land use fees, the determination of fair
market value through the use of a "net benefits" calculation
establishes a baseline for discussion that NHA believes is fatally
flawed, misleading and unfair to consumers. Again, NHA does not believe
the "net benefits" methodology is applicable to determining the value
of federal lands to a FERC-licensed hydropower project. As such, NHA
strongly encourages FERC, should the Commission decide to revisit its
program for collecting annual charges, to reject the GAO's "net
benefits" approach. NHA also believes Congress should reject the GAO's
"net benefits" analysis contained in the draft report as it undermines
the nation's oldest, largest and most reliable renewable resource.
NOTES:
[1] NHA appreciated GAO's willingness to meet with individual members of
the hydro industry and with the Association. However, for purposes of
providing comments, NHA was not allowed to retain a copy of the draft
report. As a result, these comments are based solely on notes and
memory from two viewings of the draft report.
[2] This assumes that 100% of net benefits, as calculated by the GAO
methodology, are collected as the annual land use fee.
[3] City of Vanceburg v. FERC, 571 F.2d 630, 647 (D.C. Cir 1977).
[4] Id.
[5] Id. at 646.
[6] Id at 643.
[7] Revision of Billing Procedures for Annual Charges for
Administering Part I of the Federal Power Act and to the Methodology
for Assessing Federal Land Use Charges, 52 Fed. Reg. 18,201, 18,206
(May 14, 1987).
[8] United States v. Buhler, 305 F.2d 319, 328 (5th Cir. 1962); Olson
v. United States, 54 S. Ct. 704, 708-708 (1934).
[9] Uniform Appraisal Standards for Federal Land Acquisitions,
Proceedings, Interagency Land Acquisition Conference (2000) at p. 25
(stating that land is to be valued on the use of comparable sales).
[10] Ibid, p. 61.
[11] This poll of 1,000 nationwide, registered voters was conducted
between January 19-27, 2002, by Bisconti Research, Inc. and contains a
margin of error of +/-3 percentage points.
[12] Revision of Billing Procedures for Annual Charges for
Administering Part I of the Federal Power Act and to the Methodology
for Assessing Federal Land Use Charges at 18,205.
[13] Although the order states that the calculation of the rate of return
is "discussed below," there is no such discussion in the order.
[14] Revision of Billing Procedures for Annual Charges for
Administering Part I of the Federal Power Act and to the Methodology
for Assessing Federal Land Use Charges at 18,205.
[15] Id., and 18 C.F.R. § 11.2 (B).
[16] The impetus behind the change was a study by the Inspector General
of the Department of Energy that determined that the Commission had
been undercharging licensees by approximately $15.2 million each year
for the use of about 168,000 acres of Federal land. The Inspector
General recommended revising the Commission's regulations to base
such land use charges on the current fair market value of the land
being used and the current long-term government-borrowing rate. The
Inspector General also recommended replacing the national average land
value with state-by-state averages. See Assessment of Charges Under the
Hydroelectric Program, DOE/IG Report No. 0219 (Sept. 3, 1986).
[17] The Commission also rejected other methodologies, such as using
agricultural land values as a proxy or individual appraisals. Id. at
18,202-05.
[18] Foster v. U.S., 2C1. Ct. 426, 448 (1983).
VanNess Feldman:
ATTORNEYS AT LAW:
A PROFESSIONAL CORPORATION
1050 Thomas Jefferson Street N.W.
Washington, D.C. 20007-3877
(202) 298-1800 Telephone:
(202) 338-2416 Facsimile:
Seattle, Washington (206) 623-9372:
March 31, 2003:
Mr. Barry T. Hill Director:
Natural Resources and Environment
U.S. General Accounting Office
441 G Street, N.W.
Washington, D.C. 20548:
Re: Response of Western Public Power Entities to GAO's Draft Report
entitled, "Federal Energy Regulatory Commission: Charges for Hydropower
Projects' Use of Federal Lands Need to Be Reassessed, March, 2003":
Dear Mr. Hill:
Thank you and your staff for the opportunity to review U.S. General
Accounting Office's (GAO) Draft Report entitled, "Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission: Charges for Hydropower Projects' Use of Federal
Lands Need to Be Reassessed, A Report to Congressional Requesters,
March, 2003." We appreciate the opportunity to review the materials. We
want to acknowledge and congratulate GAO for the effort of its
professional staff in this review and the cordial manner with which it
has been conducted. This is our response to the Draft Report reviewed
on March 17, 2003 on behalf of our client group of non-profit, public
power entities designated herein as the Western Public Power Entities,
including Seattle City Light (Seattle), City of Tacoma (Tacoma), Public
Utility District No. 1 of Chelan County (Chelan), Sacramento Municipal
Utility District (SMUD) and the Public Utility District No. 1 of
Douglas County (Douglas).
SUMMARY OF RESPONSE:
In its Draft Report, GAO concludes that the Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission's (FERC) charges for hydropower projects' use of federal
lands bear no relationship to the economic benefit of the federal lands
used, and that the charges FERC currently collects for hydropower
projects' use of federal lands are significantly less than fair market
value (FMV). For the reasons outlined and discussed below, we strongly
disagree.
FERC's current charges for hydropower projects' use of federal lands
meet the fundamental objectives of FERC's governing statute, the
Federal Power Act (FPA). These
charges for hydropower projects' use of federal lands are the most
reasonable and fair means of assessing annual charges while assuring
that hydropower projects are operated under comprehensive plans for
improving or developing waterways for the improvement and utilization
of waterpower development, for the adequate protection, mitigation, and
enhancement of fish and wildlife, and for other beneficial public uses,
including irrigation, flood control, water supply, and recreational and
other purposes.
Remarkably, GAO has described a method that negates the economic value
of the many public benefits provided by hydroelectric projects,
including recreation, fish and wildlife protection, wetlands
protection, irrigation and water supply, and navigation. Despite the
obvious public interest in these benefits, GAO assigns the entire
residual or net-benefit of hydropower projects on federal lands as the
FMV of the federal lands. In doing so, GAO has de facto assigned a
value of zero to all public benefits. The GAO Report makes the case,
implicitly, that efforts to ensure these public benefits for hydropower
projects should be discarded and replaced by efforts to maximize the
production of electricity (and cash).
GAO theorizes (but does not prove) that licensees receive a windfall
for their use of federal lands. GAO proposes to have FERC "cash out"
this windfall in the form of an annual charge. However, this purported
windfall does not exist. For each of the Western Public Power Entities,
none accrues profits or retains excess earnings. So, none can realize
or hold the net benefit the GAO's methodology mistakenly assigns to
them. Under such circumstances, implementing GAO's methodology and
accepting GAO's description and estimate of "FMV" would result in a
hidden tax or transfer payment on a renewable source of energy.
GAO's methodology incorrectly assumes that market forces completely
govern power prices. This is not true. Public power licensees such as
the Western Public Power Entities sell power to their retail customers
at cost. Concerning private utilities, FERC has a statutory obligation
under Parts II of the FPA to regulate wholesale rates of the
hydroelectricity generated on federal lands. Consequently, it is not
apparent how GAO reconciles its method as capturing the fair market
value of the land when both: (i) the wholesale rates of the
hydroelectricity generated are regulated (or otherwise constrained
outside the market); and (ii) the rate of return to the "investor" is
constrained by GAO's methodology, as described more fully below.
GAO's proposed methodology does not reflect reality. Very few
licensees-and none from the Western Public Power Entities group-are
authorized to charge market rates for power produced at hydroelectric
projects. Adopting this model for assessing land-use charges would
require licensees to pay annual charges based on a fabricated, perfect
market that simply does not exist.
Adopting GAO's proposed methodology would also dramatically increase
transaction costs and create tremendous administrative burdens for both
FERC and its licensees. Consider that GAO has taken nearly three years
to collect data and calculate annual values under its proposed net
benefits methodology for only 24 licensed projects. This undertaking
has required GAO to conduct meetings with licensees and retain the
services of at least three expert consultants to gather and analyze
data. Implementing the same system to assess land use charges
on an annual basis for the approximately 400 projects located on
federal land would be an overwhelming burden for FERC.
Under GAO's proposed methodology, annual charges and consumer electric
rates would fluctuate greatly from year to year, eliminating certainty
and predictability under the terms of licensees' licenses. Such radical
fluctuation would interfere with prudent utility management
and long-term planning and budgeting. This could increase the cost of
capital to owners and further result in higher rates to consumers. Such
a result would be contrary to a fundamental purpose of the FPA: to
encourage hydroelectric development in a stable, efficient and
business-like manner.
Adopting GAO's proposed methodology would also hinder the development
of the leading source of renewable energy in the United States. The
additional costs-discussed below-would make hydroelectric power less
competitive in the market.
For all of these reasons, FERC and Congress should reject GAO's
proposed methodology for charges for hydropower projects' use of
federal lands. GAO's secondary findings concerning FERC's internal
controls, information management, record keeping and billing practices
may have merit and could be the subject of further study.
DISCUSSION:
The Western Public Power Entities believe that adoption of the GAO's
net benefits methodology is an unsound approach to assessing charges
for hydropower projects' use of federal lands. Adopting these
recommendations would undermine the purposes of the FPA; sacrifice
public benefits of hydropower in pursuit of a maximum cash payout; and
dramatically increase customer costs for renewable energy. Implementing
GAO's net benefits methodology would have a profound negative impact on
hydroelectric licensees, their customers and FERC.
I. FERC's Current Methodology for Assessing Annual Charges for the Use
of Federal Land is Reasonable, Fair and Consistent with the FPA.
One of the most unsettling aspects of the Draft Report is the lack of
any discussion regarding the context or history in which FERC has
developed its methodology for collecting annual charges from its
licensees, including its assessment of the federal land-use charges
analyzed in the Draft Report. For example, the Draft Report does not
adequately describe the current FERC system, the history of FERC's
charges for hydropower projects' use of federal lands, its past
rulemakings or its rationale for adopting the current system and the
reasons that in 1987 FERC rejected a proposed method similar to GAO's
net benefit approach. Without this information, GAO's report is
incomplete.
FERC's obligation to assess annual charges for hydropower licensees'
use and occupancy of federal lands is set forth in Section 10(e)(1) of
the FPA.1 Section 10(e)(1) [NOTE 1] does not direct FERC to collect
the "FMV" of the federal lands utilized and occupied by FERC-licensed
hydropower projects. Rather, FERC is directed under the FPA only to
assess "reasonable" fees that balance land use with the public benefits
of low cost and abundant supplies of energy.
Since passage of the FPA, FERC over the years has utilized several
methodologies to assess the "reasonable" fee for licensees' use and
occupancy of federal lands. Such methods have included conducting
project-by-project appraisals and calculating a rate of return based on
a single national acreage value of federal lands. [NOTE 2]
In the 1980s, a FERC rulemaking explored several other options to set
charges for using public lands. After due deliberation and
consideration of several options--including a methodology very similar
to GAO's net benefits model in the Draft Report--FERC in 1987 adopted
the U.S. Forest Service's fee system for linear rights-of-way (ROW) on
National Forest System land. [NOTE 3] The Forest Service zonal fee
system annually produces a per acre charge on a county-by-county basis
for every state. The zonal fees were prepared for homogeneous regions
based on ROW appraisal information furnished by the utility industry.
Under FERC's current regulations, therefore, hydroelectric licensees
utilizing federal lands for transmission purposes are charged the same
fee as the Forest Service charges for transmission lines. Licensees
utilizing federal lands for other purposes of the hydroelectric
project are charged twice the transmission amount. [NOTE 4]
Upon proper consideration of the FPA, it is quite clear that FERC's
current methodology for assessing federal land-use annual charges from
hydroelectric licensees meets that statute's fundamental objectives,
namely: (1) achieving hydroelectric development of the Nation's
waterways in a manner that provides for multiple public benefits; (2)
encouraging development of this important renewable source of energy in
an efficient manner; and (3) protecting electric consumers.
First, Congress did not intend under the FPA to maximize hydroelectric
generation so that the United States could assess a royalty payment
from licensees, as the Draft Report appears to advocate. In fact,
Congress intended the opposite approach. A fundamental objective of the
FPA is to develop hydroelectric projects in a manner that achieves a
comprehensive plan for developing the Nation's waterways by requiring
licensees to develop a renewable source of energy while concurrently
providing multiple other public benefits as well. Under Section
10(a)(1), it is incumbent upon FERC to ensure that each hydroelectric
license is
best adapted to a comprehensive plan for improving or developing a
waterway or waterways for the use or benefit of interstate or foreign
commerce, for the improvement and utilization of waterpower
development, for the adequate protection, mitigation, and enhancement
of fish and wildlife (including related spawning grounds and habitat),
and for other beneficial public uses, including irrigation, flood
control, water supply, and recreational and other purposes . . . ."
[NOTE 5]
The Supreme Court, in fact, has recognized that the FPA requires FERC
to craft licenses to accommodate not only power development, but also
to ensure that the license meets "the public interest in preserving
reaches of wild rivers and wilderness areas, the preservation of
anadromous fish for commercial and recreational purposes, and the
protection of wildlife." [NOTE 6] Since the passage of the Electric
Consumers Protection Act of 1986, moreover, FERC has been required to
"give equal consideration to the purposes of energy conservation, the
protection, mitigation of damage to, and enhancement of, fish and
wildlife (including related spawning grounds and habitat), the
protection of recreational opportunities, and the preservation of
other aspects of environmental quality." [NOTE 7]
Second, contrary to the Draft Report, which would have FERC adopt a
mechanism for assessing annual charges that would fluctuate
dramatically from year to year, a fundamental purpose of the FPA is to
encourage hydroelectric development in a stable, efficient and business
like manner. FERC and the courts have long found that one of the main
purposes of the FPA is to "encourage the orderly development of
plentiful supplies of electricity." [NOTE 8] Indeed,
"[o]ne of the main purposes of the [FPA] is to encourage the
development of hydroelectric power." [NOTE 9] A primary mechanism for
encouraging the stable and efficient development of this renewable
resource is for FERC to issue licenses with fixed terms sufficient to
make the licensee secure in its investment. [NOTE 10] The FPA itself
precludes unilateral changes to license terms and conditions by FERC
or Congress, [NOTE 11] and even upon expiration of
the existing license, FERC cannot simply change license terms in the
new license without providing reasoned explanation. [NOTE 12]
The policy for encouraging stable and efficient hydroelectric
development of the Nation's waterways continues today. The Bush
Administration, in its recent National Energy Policy report, recognized
hydroelectricity as the leading source of renewable source of energy
"that produces no emissions" and that "will continue to be an important
source of U.S. energy for the future." [NOTE 13] -In addition,
Congress has continued to articulate a policy for encouraging
efficient development of hydroelectric resources, as evidenced by
pending bills that would provide incentives for development of
incremental hydropower. [NOTE 14]
Third, in contrast to the Draft Report, which would seem to
dramatically increase FERC's annual charges for hydropower licensees'
use of federal land, as well as its annual charges for the
administration of the FPA, a fundamental policy of the FPA is to ensure
a supply of renewable energy to electric consumers "at reasonable
prices." [NOTE 15] This is particularly relevant with respect to
FERC's annual charges program at issue in the GAO Draft Report, as the
FPA itself specifically directs that FERC, when establishing annual
charges, "shall seek to avoid increasing the price to the consumers of
power by such charges. [NOTE 16]
These fundamental objectives of the FPA do not express a Congressional
intent for FERC to recoup federal land use fees at FMV, as implied by
the Draft Report. In contrast to other statutes requiring reimbursement
at FMV, [NOTE 17] Congress only authorized FERC to recoup a
"reasonable annual charge ... for recompensing [the United States] for
the use, occupancy, and enjoyment of its lands or other property."
[NOTE 18] By authorizing FERC to assess "reasonable" annual charges,
Congress required that FERC devise a methodology of calculating annual
charges "within the context of the larger purposes of the Act,"
[NOTE 19] i.e., the multiple public benefits
provided by hydroelectric licensees, encouraging efficient development
of the Nation's waterways, and protecting electric consumers. This
fundamental concept was perhaps best explained by the D.C. Circuit:
[T]he Commission must set a reasonable charge by considering all
relevant factors and arriving at a charge which minimizes consumer
costs, encourages power development, but at the same time, compensates
the Government to some extent for the benefit it has conferred on the
licensee. [NOTE 20]
Unlike the Draft Report, FERC's current methodology for calculating and
assessing annual charges for the use of federal lands recognizes these
bedrock purposes of the FPA and the context in which Congress has
required an assessment of annual charges. FERC has deliberately chosen
a straightforward, transparent, and stable means to calculate its
federal land-use charges and has specifically rejected proposals to
implement more complex, cost-based systems. Such a methodology is fully
supported by the FPA.
[End of table]
II. GAO's Proposed Methodology Ignores the Bedrock Objectives of the FPA
by Failing to Account for the Multiple Public Benefits Provided by
Hydroelectric Projects.
The Western Public Power Entities simply cannot understand why GAO has
elected to propose a complex, unpredictable and inefficient system for
FERC's collection of land-use fees. Not only does FERC's current system
adequately capture the "reasonable annual charges" that are authorized
under the FPA, but FERC has squarely rejected very similar
methodologies to that proposed by GAO as being inconsistent with the
purposes of the FPA. In rejecting a net benefits approach for
calculating annual charges for the use of government dams, FERC found
that a flat rate approach
is relatively simple and straightforward both for the Commission to
administer and for potential developers to factor into their project
feasibility studies. This will enhance the certainty of hydro project
development .... A flat rate method does not require the complex
calculations inherent in the generic [net benefits] method .... This
complexity would interfere unnecessarily with the Commission's need for
administrative workability and licensees' need for predictability.
[NOTE 21]
The Draft Report appears to criticize this and other reasons
articulated by FERC for not adopting more rigorous methodologies for
assessing annual charges, implying that FERC's current system is a
result of administrative expediency to appease the hydroelectric
industry and avoid litigation. Such a sweeping and dismissive approach,
however, only illustrates that GAO failed to consider the underlying
purposes and policies of the FPA and the context in which annual
charges must be assessed. Certainly, FERC is entitled to consider its
own administrative costs when determining an appropriate method of
setting annual charges. Not only has the Supreme Court recognized this,
[NOTE 22] current directives of the Office of Management and Budget
require agencies to implement efficient cost-recovery systems.
[NOTE 23] Considering that all of FERC's costs for administering the
FPA are passed through directly to licensees, and that Congress
specifically directed FERC to avoid setting annual charges that would
result in higher rates to electric consumers, [NOTE 24] FERC's
concerns about unnecessarily increasing its administrative costs are
quite valid.
FERC's understanding and appreciation of the underlying policies of the
FPA have caused it to reject, on at least three separate occasions, an
income approach-very similar to the methodology advocated by the Draft
Report-in calculating land use charges for licensees' use of federal
lands. Not only did FERC find that such a system "would interfere
unnecessarily with
the Commission's need for administrative workability" in the annual
charges program, [NOTE 25] but such methodology also
would charge a royalty ... as though the Federal land being used was
producing the power. This overlooks the fact that many projects use a
combination of Federal and private lands, and that the power output is
a result of many factors (water rights, head, project structure) and
not just the acreage of Federal land involved." [NOTE 26]
In its attempt to develop a sophisticated and comprehensive methodology
for capturing land-use value, GAO has developed a method that negates
the economic value of the public benefits provided by hydroelectric
projects. These public benefits include recreation, fish and wildlife
protection, wetlands protection, irrigation and water supply, and
navigation. Moreover, as discussed above, Congress has required that
FERC give equal consideration to these benefits and power benefits
during the licensing process.
GAO states in its report that "We did not attempt to estimate the value
of the federal lands used for purposes other than hydropower."
[NOTE 27] This statement, however, does not capture the full effect
of GAO's application of the net-benefits approach. Since GAO assigns
the entire residual or net-benefit as the FMV of federal land, it has
de facto assigned a value of zero to all public benefits. [NOTE 28]
Not attempting to estimate the value of public benefits and assigning
public benefits a value of zero differ greatly. Clearly, this is a
major defect in the approach. [NOTE 29]
Putting aside, for a moment, the estimation of the value of public
benefits provided by hydroelectric projects, GAO's methodology creates
a quasi-academic vacuum, unrelated to a well-established legal and
policy framework. GAO does this in two ways. First, by assigning a zero
value to public benefits, benefits that are mandated by the FPA and
rigorously imposed by FERC, GAO makes the case, implicitly, that
efforts to ensure these public benefits should be replaced by efforts
to maximize the production of electricity from these hydroelectric
projects. Second, GAO theorizes that licensees receive a windfall for
their use of federal lands
the estimated fair market value of the federal lands used by our sample
of 24 hydropower projects is a least $157 million annually and, under
some market conditions, the value of these lands is worth hundreds of
millions of dollars more. In comparison, FERC collected about $2.7
million in annual charges from these projects in 2002. [NOTE 30]
GAO proposes to have FERC cash out this windfall in the form of an
annual charge.
This purported windfall, indeed, does not exist. None of the Western
Public Power Entities accrues profits or retains excess earnings. More
importantly, for each of these entities, the established electricity
rates are sufficient to cover costs with no provision made for profit
or retained earnings. Thus, GAO's postulation of a windfall, and that
the federal government is remiss by not collecting it, does not reflect
the actual situation of the Western Public Power Entities.
By ignoring the public benefits of hydroelectric projects and by
assuming a "potential market price" (e.g., the California Power
Exchange Price) rather than prices actually charged, GAO's model
assumes that every acre within a project is or should be maximized for
the production of power, at the expense of these other public benefits.
In the context of the existing and well established legal and policy
framework, this premise is flawed. Even in terms of economic theory,
this premise can be questioned because whereas "kilowatt hours" can be
provided by any number of substitutes-GAO assumes that gas-fired power
plants are the least cost source for substitutes-these public lands are
"scarce," perhaps even unique with respect to recreation, fish,
wildlife and biodiversity, and the public goods they provide cannot be
found elsewhere.
In summary, GAO's methodology would propose that FERC, instead of
ensuring a comprehensive plan for developing a waterway by requiring
licensees to maintain multiple-use projects, should require licensees
to maximize power development on federal lands so that the federal
government can maximize an annual charge. Such an approach is contrary
to any notion of "sustainable development" of natural resources and
would run counter to federal policies and well-established legal
framework in this regard.
III. GAO's Proposed Methodology is the Wrong Tool for Calculating FMV of
Federal Lands.
At a fundamental level, GAO equates FMV with the "net benefits
approach." GAO states specifically, that "net benefits analysis
estimates the difference between the value of the power produced and
the cost to produce it. This difference is our estimate of the land's
annual fair market value. [NOTE 31] GAO does this, however, without
any elaboration or justification. Furthermore, the Draft Report
somewhat misleadingly states that "FERC has acknowledged that using
FMV is the most reasonable method for compensating the federal
government for the use of land," [NOTE 32] when in fact FERC rejected
the net benefits approach for determining FMV. [NOTE 33] This is a
troubling foundation for such an important change, one which affects
to some extent, national energy policy.
More specifically, GAO's methodology assumes that the "highest and best
use" of all lands within a licensed hydroelectric project is the
generation of electricity. This results from the logical conclusion
that the value of the federal land is based on the production of
hydroelectric power at market rates, whether each acre of land is used
for power production or not. Earlier we stated how this assumption runs
counter to the existing legal and regulatory framework, and how
Congress has required that FERC give equal consideration to non-power
or public benefits and power benefits during the licensing process. We
pointed out that many acres of federal land included within the
boundary of licensed projects have never been used for the purpose of
generating hydroelectricity, but instead are included within the
project only for the broader purposes of the FPA, such as recreation,
wildlife enhancement, and wetlands mitigation.
Furthermore, the Draft Report criticizes FERC's existing methodology as
being unrelated to the actual value of federal land. Yet the values
derived from GAO's proposed methodology are even more divorced from any
intrinsic land-based element. In fact, GAO's calculation of the
"Federal Net Benefit (value of the land)" is based on an equation with
well over 12 variables; only one variable is related to the physical
elements of the land: the percentage of total project property that is
federal land. The Draft Report acknowledges that changes in weather,
rainfall patterns, regulatory constraints, costs of fuels, and
significant changes in supply and demand for electricity all
"dramatically" affect the value of federal lands. Consequently,
dramatic year-to-
year changes in the value of federal land-and presumably in the fees
collected-will result when a common-sense question would be: What about
the land has actually changed?
Table la has been taken from the Draft Report. Table lb provides a
measure for lands that may be considered similar; it is provided only
for comparison purposes. Since GAO equates its proposed net benefits
approach with FMV, it is puzzling to see GAO's FMV results for these
lands vary so greatly from year to year. It is even more puzzling to
see the FMV of hydroelectric project lands change from a large negative
value in one year to a large positive value the next year, when no
physical changes to the land have occurred. Indeed, these large
fluctuations are an artifact of the methodology and, we presume, would
not track well with other measures of land FMV, such as those employed
by appraisals of comparable parcels.
Table la: GAO'S Net Benefit Approach for Calculating FMV of Federal
Land (in dollars):
1998; 1999; % change; 2000; % change.
Boundary; WA; 26,605,710; 67,361,992; 153%; 297,596,987; 342%.
Rock Island; WA; 139,250; 596,309; 328%; 3,081,965; 417%.
Rocky Reach; WA; 775,377; 1,819,369; 135%; 7,408,316; 307%.
Skagit River; WA; (22,990,815); 15,289,797; 167%; 165,136,818; 980%.
Upper American River; CA; (39,178,080); (34,344,422); 12%; 68,686,643;
300%.
(Source: GAO Draft Report):
[End of table]
TABLE lb: USDA Agricultural Land Values (in dollars/acre):
1998; 1999; % change; 2000; % change.
Washington State:
farm real estate; 1,190; 1,190; 0%; 1,200; 1%.
pasture; 550; 540; -2%; 490; -9%.
irrigated cropland; 3,400; 3,600; 6%; 3,500; -3%.
non-irrigated cropland; 840; 760; -10%; 700; -8%.
California:
farm real estate; 2,610; 2,770; 6%; 2,850; 3%.
pasture; 1,050; 1,050; 0%; 1,000; -5%.
irrigated cropland; 5,600; 6,100; 9%; 6,400; 5%.
non-irrigated cropland; 1,700; 1,580; -7%; 1,400; -11%.
(Source: USDA, National Agricultural Statistics Service, Agricultural
Land Values, August 2002):
[End of table]
Because the value of the federal lands changes dramatically under GAO's
methodology from year to year based on weather and rainfall patterns-as
well as regulatory constraints and significant changes in supply and
demand for fuels and electricity-it is not unrealistic to state that
the methodology proposed by GAO seems a more appropriate measure for
the "FMV" of the water that flows over the land than a FMV of the land
itself.
The methodology proposed by GAO is not a mere academic exercise. The
consequence of GAO's efforts would be a change in FERC's annual land-
use charges. If FERC were to build on the proposed GAO methodology but
assess an annual land-use charge proportional to GAO's methodology for
estimated "FMV," the result would be nothing more than a royalty -a
hidden tax or transfer payment on a renewable source of energy. This
royalty (or hidden tax or transfer payment) results because GAO's
methodology defines a "FMV" of federal lands as a measure of net
income-with a fixed, regulated, "not-to-exceed" rate of return on
investment of the licensee generating power at the project. While this
method may be an appropriate measure of valuing a captured resource,
such as oil, gas or water, it is not an appropriate measure for valuing
land.
IV. GAO's Methodology Is Based on Theoretical Markets and Incorrect
Assumptions.
There are a number of assumptions including the assumption of a
theoretical market-built into GAO's proposed methodology. In this
section we identify the major assumptions with a brief discussion of
why they lead to an inappropriate application in the context of land-
use charges.
GAO's approach to assess "FMV" is presented with the underlying
assumption that the U.S. electric industry is currently undergoing
substantial restructuring and the trend is toward more deregulation and
market-based pricing. While this assumption may have been accurate
three or four years ago, since the 2001/2002 California energy crisis
and the fallout from the Enron energy trading and fraud scandal, states
have halted or significantly pulled back from their restructuring
efforts. In fact, as of February 2003, six states have suspended or
delayed their efforts to deregulate the electric generation and
delivery system; only 17 states plus the District of Columbia have
active restructuring plans, and in 27 states restructuring plans are
not active (see Figure 1 below).
Figure 1: Status of Electric Industry Restructuring Activitiy (February
2003):
[See PDF for image]
Restructuring Active ® Restructuring Delayed ® Restructuring Suspended
Restructuring NotActive:
Source: DOE Energy Information Administration:
[End of figure]
GAO's assumption regarding restructuring is particularly troubling,
given that the most hydroelectric projects utilizing federal lands are
located in states where restructuring activities are not active, or
have been delayed or suspended. [NOTE 34]
GAO's methodology incorrectly assumes that market forces completely
govern power prices-that is, each link of the chain from production to
consumption is based on market forces. Public power licensees such as
the Western Public Power sell power to their retail customers at cost.
Concerning private utilities, unlike oil and gas leases, grazing
permits, special use permits, and other federal government
authorizations-FERC has a statutory obligation under Parts II and III
of the FPA to regulate wholesale rates of the hydroelectricity
generated on federal lands. Consequently, we are puzzled that GAO
regards its method as capturing the fair market value of the land when
both: (i) the wholesale rates of the hydroelectricity generated is
regulated (or otherwise and constrained outside the market); and (ii)
the rate of return to the "investor" is constrained by GAO's
methodology.
Even in a restructured market, the rates of public power entities will
never be at market prices. Such entities are government owned, have no
shareholders, and are required to sell all power to their constituents
at cost. Thus, any and all increases to FERC's federal land-use charges
would have to be completely passed through to consumers.
A significant number of projects located on federal land are licensed
to public power entities. In GAO's sample of 24 projects, for example,
9 are public power facilities. Assuming that the annual land-use charge
would be GAO's estimate of the FMV of federal lands for 2003, and using
the estimate of existing FERC land-use fees for 2002 as a surrogate for
2003, we would expect a direct increase of $94 million in annual
charges that must be passed on to consumers in the form of rate
increases regardless of market conditions (See Table 2 below).
Table 2: GAO's Estimate of the FMV of Federal Land that Would Result in
Rate Increases for Customers of Public Power Entities (in dollars):
[See PDF for image]
[End of table]
GAO assumes that even if rate increases would result from this proposed
methodology-that is, the purported windfall does not come from
investors' profits but as increased prices to utility customers-it
would be appropriate because currently taxpayers are subsidizing
utility customers, i.e., electricity rates are undervalued. [NOTE 35]
We believe GAO is
wrongly viewing this subject and is ascribing subsidies where they do
not exist. Unlike the case of federal dam-use charges, the federal
government has incurred no costs for these lands. In fact, it is clear
from the history of the FPA that its purpose was to encourage non-
federal development of hydroelectricity throughout the United States,
because the federal government was not in a position to incur the cost
of developing these sites. Thus, there are no costs that have been
assumed by the federal government for which utility consumers have not
paid. It seems, rather, that GAO wrongly equates a loss of future
potential revenue stream with a subsidy.
A particularly troubling assumption is that GAO's proposal relies on
theoretical market prices, rather than actual revenue to calculate the
net income of a project. GAO recognizes this and states in its draft
report "our estimates of the value of power generally differ from the
revenues that the project owners earn for the sale of the hydropower
that they generate." [NOTE 36]
GAO has taken for the price of electricity the
price from the California Power Exchange (CAPX)-applied it to all
licensees surveyed-and then has taken this hourly wholesale market
price and multiplied it by each unit's hourly electrical generation
rate. In fact, the Western Public Power Entities have not received and
will not receive CAPX prices for each hour of electrical generation.
Consequently, the model inappropriately leads to an overestimate of the
FMV of the land; something that puts into question the notion that this
method accurately assess "market value" at all. Table 3 illustrates
this overestimation for two projects of the Western Public Power
Entities.
Table 3: Examples of Actual Revenues Compared with GAO's Estimate of
Revenues (in dollars):
[See PDF for image]
Notes: Net electricity generation and actual revenues provided by
licensees. CAPX Price from:
GAO Draft report. Calculation of GAO's estimated revenues is CAPX
multiplied by net electricity generation. (Source: Information from
Licensees and GAO Draft Report):
[End of table]
Not only is this approach doubtful in the context of market estimation,
the D.C. Circuit has found that only an approach that uses actual
values would be reasonable as required by Section 10(e):
The Commission's interpretation that Section 10(e) authorizes dam-use
charges based on the actual value of dam use to the specific licensee
is a reasonable one, and as such is entitled to great weight. We find
nothing in the Act, which militates against this construction.
Moreover, we believe that this interpretation is most consistent with
the notion of compensation in that each licensee is to be charged in
direct proportion to the fiscal benefit it actually receives.
[NOTE 37]
Because very few licensees are authorized to charge market rates for
power produced at hydroelectric projects-and none from the Western
Public Power Entities group-GAO's proposed methodology does not reflect
reality. Furthermore, the adoption of this model as a basis for
assessing land-use charges would require licensees to pay annual
charges based not on reality, but on a fabricated, perfect market that
simply does not exist.
GAO's methodology can and does produce "negative values" for the value
of federal lands. These values result from the logic of the net
benefits approach and are constrained by the fixed, regulated "return
on investment" assumed by GAO. If the rate of return is allowed to vary
more widely as it does in reality-then the number and extent of
"negative values" for the value of federal lands can be even greater.
We understand GAO's explanation that negative values result from either
a rate of return on investment that is lower than the fixed rate, or,
indeed, a negative rate of return on investment. Because GAO's
methodology constrains the upside of the rate of return-i.e., it can be
no greater than 7.22 percent-it would be patently unfair not to
constrain the downside. How FERC would handle the likelihood of
negative values for land-use charges is discussed in section V below.
GAO states that "Wholesale market prices are a more accurate reflection
of the economic value of power." [NOTE 38] We take exception to this
statement, as wholesale market prices do not account completely for the
provision of public benefits. (See our discussion above in Section Il
regarding FPA's mandate for providing public benefits.) In fact, to the
extent that wholesale market prices reflect public benefits, if at all,
the GAO methodology may be inaccurate for the production of hydropower.
In particular, if wholesale market prices used by GAO reflect the value
of air pollution and control mitigation measures taken at fossil fuel
fired power plants, then those "market prices" inaccurately reflect the
value of the environmental enhancement measures taken at hydropower
production plants.
Presuming that GAO wishes to accurately reflect the economic value of
federal lands, it needs to provide estimates for the many public
benefits provided related to irrigation, recreation, wetlands
management, fisheries, credit for carbon-dioxide avoidance, and
biodiversity
management. Values for these actions, provided to the public at low
cost or without charge, result from the investments and ongoing
management of the utility owners, and therefore, should be subtracted
from the "net benefit value" as calculated by GAO's proposed
methodology. We agree that each of these elements is difficult to
quantify, but GAO made other, complex estimates in its Draft Report,
and to the extent the GAO wishes to reflect all economic values, it
should revise its methodology to be more comprehensive and appropriate.
V. GAO's Draft Report Failed to Consider Implementation Issues.
In evaluating the tangible effects of GAO's proposed methodology, we
identified a number of troubling issues. Below, we present the issues
with a brief discussion of why they lead to an impractical process for
assessing FERC related land-use charges.
GAO's proposed methodology only goes so far: it presents a way to
estimate the FMV of federal lands, but does not instruct FERC as to the
proper way to convert this value to an annual land use fee.
Consequently, FERC would need to undertake a large, multi-year effort
to develop
a complementary methodology that would adjust the "full" FMV of federal
lands to a reasonable fee.
If FERC were to adopt GAO's proposed methodology, it would dramatically
increase transaction costs and create tremendous administrative burdens
for both FERC and its licensees. We note that GAO has taken nearly
three years to collect data and calculate annual values under its
proposed net benefits methodology for only 24 licensed projects. This
undertaking has required GAO to conduct meetings with licensees and
retain the services of at least three expert consultants to gather and
analyze data. It would be an overwhelming burden if FERC were required
to implement the same system to assess land use charges on an annual
basis for the approximately 400 projects located on federal land.
[NOTE 39]
Implementation of this system would require licensees to hire
additional accountants, economists, appraisers and other consultants to
provide, on an annual basis, the additional data that would be required
for FERC to calculate the annual charge. Our "best guess" is that a
land use charge process based on GAO's proposed method would cost up to
$85,000 annually for each of (approximately) 400 licensees and would
require an additional 10 full-time-equivalent (FTE) staff for FERC for
the program. [NOTE 40]
It is important to note that such system would be fully
and directly detrimental to consumers, because Section 10(e)(1)
requires FERC to pass through all its administrative costs to
hydroelectric licensees. [NOTE 41]
Consequently, the 10 FTEs would increase costs to hydroelectric
licensees by up to $1.25 million annually.
It is important to keep in mind that the Draft Report has suggested
that FERC needs to implement additional internal-control measures to
ensure the reliability of its databases. This could increase the above
"best guesses" by as much as $9.5 million annually. [NOTE 42]
Summing up our "best guesses" of each of these components, we estimate
an annual increase in fees-excluding the actual land-use charges of up
to $45 million solely to offset increased transaction costs.
In analyzing the legal implications of such a system, we conclude that
implementation would require an OMB rulemaking, which could very well
trigger the Paperwork Reduction Act. Additionally, we believe that the
implementation of an annual land-use charge system based on GAO's
proposed methodology would require a statutory provision to allow for
the collection of royalty payments for hydropower. More important,
given the questionable assumptions, complex calculations, and
extraordinarily high annual charges, FERC's implementation of GAO's
proposed methodology would lead to initial and annual lawsuits
challenging the annual charge assessment. We have yet to estimate the
costs associated with rulemaking and legal challenges, but we believe
they would be high and contribute to an escalation of transaction costs
launched by the proposed methodology.
Perhaps the most detrimental consequence of adopting a land-use charge
system based on GAO's proposed methodology would be a stifling of the
development of the leading source of renewable energy in the United
States. The additional costs-discussed above-would make hydroelectric
power less competitive in the market. Also, land-use charges calculated
pursuant to GAO's proposed methodology would fluctuate greatly from
year to year, eliminating certainty and predictability under the terms
of licensees' licenses. Recall from Table 1 a above, the large year-to-
year changes in GAO's estimate of land value. Such radical fluctuation
would interfere with prudent utility management and long-term planning
and budgeting. [NOTE 43]
Budgeting for such fluctuations may force utility
owners to expand financing options and lines of credit to weather the
year-to-year changes. This could increase the cost of capital to owners
and further result in higher rates to consumers.
We also appreciate that budgeting for such fluctuations will be
extremely difficult for FERC, since: (1) the revenue stream will be
highly unpredictable from year to year; and (2):
presumably FERC would need to provide for "refunds" for years where the
value of federal lands is "negative." (FERC will be hard pressed to
justify why it would develop a system that would shield itself from a
loss of revenue-i.e., not providing refunds-while passing all
commercial risk completely onto licensees. Implementation of GAO's
proposal without a refund mechanism would essentially authorize the
federal government to reap the rewards of power development without
having to assume the liabilities and risks associated with
constructing, operating and maintaining the project; we believe legal
challenges will prove this position untenable.):
Building such barriers to the development of the leading source of
renewable energy in the United States would also adversely impact the
environment. Keep in mind that every megawatt-hour of electricity
produced by a hydroelectric plant avoids 0.9 metric tons of carbon
dioxide-a greenhouse gas that contributes to global warming as well as
sulfur dioxide and other pollutants. Consequently, the annual
production of hydroelectric power in the United States, some 224
million megawatt-hours, currently avoids approximately 200 million tons
of carbon dioxide and a proportionate amount of other pollutants.
[NOTE 44] Eliminating hydroelectric generation would have negative
consequences to the electricity grid as well. Hydroelectric
facilities, because they can be brought on-line almost
instantaneously, are invaluable as peaking facilities and provide
stability to the grid.
Finally, implementing a land-use charge system based on GAO's proposed
methodology would weaken the economies of communities highly dependent
upon hydroelectricity. In its Draft Report GAO recognizes that
increases to electrical rates could have a depressive effect on local
economies because of higher unemployment, inflation, and presumably
lower disposable income, etc. We agree and further believe that the
negative economic effects will be, at a local level, significant. Also,
we point out that taxpayers would not benefit from increased annual
charges from hydroelectric licensees further refuting GAO's assumption
that increased charges will offset taxpayers' subsidies (see the
discussion in Section IV above). Under the FPA, only 12.5 percent of
the revenues generated from FERC's federal land-use charges are
deposited into the general treasury. The other 87.5 percent goes to the
Reclamation fund (50 percent of total revenues) and to the state in
which the federal lands are located (37.5 percent). [NOTE 45]
Under a system implementing GAO's proposed methodology, therefore,
hydroelectric licensees would be subsidizing unpaid debts for the
construction of reclamation projects.
The impact to taxpayer consumers of public power entities would be
especially disastrous. Not only would rates to consumers be increased
as a result of the annual charge, but also rates to these consumers
would be increased as a result of FERC's increased administrative
charges to implement this system. [NOTE 46]
These higher charges to electricity consumers would come
with no commensurate gain in electricity quantity or quality instead,
these higher charges would be used solely to offset the higher
transaction costs created under a system that is based on GAO's
proposed methodology.
CONCLUSION:
It is clear that GAO's net benefits approach to determining charges for
hydropower projects' use of federal lands is undesirable, impractical
and extremely costly. FERC and Congress should reject GAO's proposed
methodology for charges for hydropower projects' use of federal lands.
GAO's secondary findings concerning FERC's internal controls,
information management, record keeping and billing practices may have
merit and could be the subject of further study.
The Western Public Power Entities appreciate this opportunity to
comment on the GAO's Draft Report and look forward to continuing
discussions on this important topic. If you have any questions
regarding the contents of this comment, please feel free to contact the
undersigned.
Sincerely,
Michael A. Swiger
Steven Richardson
Charles R. Sensiba:
Counsel to the Western Public Power Entities:
Signed by Michael A. Swiger:
NOTES:
[1] 16 U.S.C. § 803(e)(1) (2000).
[2] See 52 Fed. Reg. 18,201, at 18,202 (May 14, 1987).
[3] See id. at 18,204-06.
[4] 18 C.F.R. § 11.2 (2002).
[5] 16 U.S.C. § 803(a)(1) (2000)
[6] Udall v. FPC, 387 U.S. 428,450 (1967).
[7] Pub. L. No. 99-495, § 3(a), 100 Stat. 1243, 1243 (codified at 16
U.S.C. § 797(e) (2000)) (emphasis added).
[8] NAACP v. FPC, 425 U.S. 662, 670 (1976).
[9] City of Vanceburg v. FERC, 571 F.2d 630, 632 (D.C. Cir. 1977),
cert. denied, 439 U.S. 818 (1978).
[10] E.g., Pac. Gas & Elec. Co. v. FERC, 720 F.2d 78, 83, 87
(D.C. Cir. 1983).
[11] 16 U.S.C. §§ 799, 822 (2000).
[12] E.g., Wis. Valley Improvement Co. v. FERC, 236 F.3d 738
(D.C. Cir. 2001).
[13] National Energy Policy: Report of the National Energy Policy
Development Group at 1-8 (2001).
[14] E.g., H.R. 991, 108th Cong. § 2 (2003); H.R. 1294, 108th Cong.
§ 1 (2003); S. 464, 108th Cong. § 2 (2003).
[15] nAACP, 425 U.S. at 670; see also Atl. Ref. Co. v. Pub. Serv.
Comm'n, 79 S. Ct. 1246, 1253-54 (1959); Fla. Power & Light Co. v.
Pub. Serv. Comm'n, 617 F.2d 809, 816 (D.C. Cir. 1980); Town of
Alexandria v. FPC, 555 F.2d 1020, 1028 (D.C. Cir. 1977).
[16] 16 U.S.C. § 803(e)(1) (2000).
[17] Eg., 16 U.S.C. § 497b(b)(8) (2000) (providing that ski area
permits "shall be subject to a permit fee based on fair market value
in accordance with applicable law"); 30 U.S.C. § 185(2) (2000)
(providing that "the holder of a right-of-way or permit shall
reimburse the United States ... the fair market rental value of the
right-of-way or permit"); 43 U.S.C. § 1764(g) (2000) (providing that
the "holder of a right-of-way shall pay in advance the fair market
value thereof').
[18] 16 U.S.C. § 803(e)(1) (emphasis added).
[19] Portland Gen. Elec. Co., 20 FERC T 61,294, at 61,562 (1982).
[20] City of Vanceburg v. FERC, 571 F.2d 630, 647 (D.C. Cir. 1977),
cert. denied, 439 U.S. 818 (1978).
[21] 49 Fed. Reg. at 22,770, at 22,772 (June 1, 1984).
[22] Permian Basin Area Rate Cases, 390 U.S. 747, 777 (1968).
[23] OMB Circular No. A-25 § 7(f) (requiring that "[e]very effort
should be made to keep the costs of collection to a minimum").
[24] 16 U.S.C. § 803(e)(1) (2000); see also 42 U.S.C. § 7178(a)(1)
(2000).
[25] 2s See 52 Fed. Reg. 18,201 (May 14, 1987); 49 Fed. Reg. 22,770
(June 1, 1984); Portland Gen. Elec., 20 FERC T 61,294 (1982).
[26] 52 Fed. Reg. 18,201, at 18,206 (May 14, 1987).
[27] Draft Report at 10.
[28] Put in words, GAO's "equation" for estimating the fair market
value of the land is to take the maximum revenues that could be
realized by selling hydroelectric power at market rates; then subtract
all costs including operations and maintenance, a portion of corporate
general and administrative expenses related to the project, and an
annual depreciation value of physical assets; finally, subtract a rate
of return of 7.22%; the resulting number, or residual, represents the
fair market value of the land.
[29] GAO addresses the issue of the economic value of public benefits
in a rather oblique manner. GAO states in the Draft Report:
While the cost to operate a hydropower project generally remains
stable, low electricity prices can dramatically reduce revenues and
thereby reduce or eliminate any net benefit for that year. For some of
our sample projects, a negative net benefit estimate may also mean that
the project was built for other purposes, such as irrigation. As such,
the capital cost of the project included the cost associated with both
irrigation and hydropower production. For these projects other purposes
are emphasized over the production of hydropower.... As a result the
revenue potential from hydropower operations is not maximized and the
project has a minimal or negative net benefit.
Draft Report at 19. This
line of reasoning suggests that for a minimal or negative net benefit
value it would be impossible to know if the cause of the lower value is
lower than expected electricity prices (or higher O&M cost) or the
result of public benefits produced by the project. For example, if one
project has a net benefit value of negative $1,000 and a second project
a value of positive $1,000, is it necessarily true that the first
project provides more public benefits than the second? More important,
GAO in its Draft Report equates the "excess" depreciated capital cost
(e.g., for an irrigation system) with the "economic value" of the
public benefits, when this is an approach that GAO explicitly rejects
for calculating the fair market value of the land.
[30] Draft Report at 5.
[31] Id. at 3.
[32] Id. at 4.
[33] 49 Fed. Reg. 22,770 (June 1, 1984). The Draft Report also states
that the Confederated Tribes of Warm Springs Reservation in Oregon
("Confederated Tribes") have settled with FERC using a net benefits
method and that the Bureau of Indian Affairs ("BIA") has adopted, as a
stated position, the net benefits method as a starting point in
negotiations between tribes and owners of hydropower projects. Draft
Report at 38. In fact, FERC in Portland General Electric Co., 20 FERC ~
61,294 (1982), rejected an annual net benefits calculation for setting
annual charges for the licensee's use of the lands of the Confederated
Tribes. In addition, GAO cites no support for its characterization of
BIA's position, and it is FERC's longstanding policy that annual
charges for the use of tribal lands are established through
negotiations between the licensee and individual tribe, not BIA. E.g.,
Wis. Power & Light Co., 97 FERC ~ 61,054, at 61,294 (2001); City of
Tacoma, 84 FERC T 61,107, at 61,578 (1998); Portland Gen. Elec. Co., 31
FERC ~ 61,306 (1985); Ariz. Pub. Serv. Co., 39 F.P.C. 955, 963 (1968).
[34] Compare Draft Report at 8 (Figure 1).
[35] Draft Report at 6.
[36] Draft Report at 42.
[37] City of Vanceburg v. FERC, 571 F.2d 630, 646 (D.C. Cir. 1977), cert.
denied, 439 U.S. 818 (1978) (emphasis added).
[38] Draft Report at 38.
[39] This result is particularly troubling in light of previous GAO
efforts recognizing the need to develop efficient-cost recovery
programs. E.g., GAO/RCED-99-165, Indian Programs. BIA Should Streamline
Its Process for Estimating Land Rental Values (1999).
[40] These estimates include part-time availability for clerical and
accounting staff (estimated at $25,000 per year, fully loaded);
engineering consultation regarding replacement costs every five years
($50,000 every five years); financial auditing services ($30,000 per
year); management time ($20,000 per year). This $85,000 per year per
licensee is multiplied by 400 licensees for an annual cost of $34
million). FTE estimates are based on one additional FERC FTE per 40
licensees at approximately $125,000 per FTE (Sources: FERC's "First
Annual State of the Agency Report, FY2000" October 2000; GAO's
"Department of Energy: Funding and Workforce Reduced, but Spending
Remains Stable," April 1997; and Office of Inspector General,
Department of the Treasury, "Information Report: A Primer on 5 Federal
Financial Regulatory Agencies," December 2001.):
[41] 16 U.S.C. § 803(a)(1) (2000).
[42] These estimates include part-time availability for clerical and
accounting staff (estimated at $12,500 per year, fully loaded); and
management time ($10,000 per year). This $22,500 per year per licensee
is multiplied by 400 licensees for an annual cost of $9 million). FTE
estimates are based on one additional FERC FTE per 100 licensees at
approximately $125,000 per FTE (sources as above).
[43] See 49 Fed. Reg. at 22,772 (finding that the complexity of an
income approach "would interfere unnecessarily with ... licensees'
need for predictability").
[44] Energy Information Administration, Office of Coal, Nuclear,
Electric and Alternative Fuels, Coal and Electric Analysis Branch,
U.S. Department of Energy, "Electricity Generation and Environmental
Externalities: Case Studies," September 1995; Energy Information
Administration, U.S. Department of Energy, "International Energy Annual
2001."
[45] See 16 U.S.C. § 810 (2000).
[46] See: 16 U.S.C. § 803(e)(1) (2000).
The following are GAO's comments on the National Hydropower
Association's letter dated March 31, 2003.
GAO's Comments:
1. We do not specifically recommend that FERC adopt our methodology as
a mechanism for levying annual charges, as NHA later acknowledges on
page 2 of its comments. Instead, we used the net benefits approach as a
tool to value the federal lands used by a sample of FERC-licensed
hydropower projects. In so doing, we found that FERC is collecting only
a very small percentage of the federal lands' value in its current
annual charge system. We also recognize that an annual charge that
better reflects the value of land used for hydropower may likely raise
consumers' costs. Consequently, we recommend that FERC reassess its
current annual charge system, and in making any revisions, FERC
consider "the federal land's fair market value as well as the competing
goals of encouraging hydropower development and avoiding unreasonable
rate increases to consumers." Under the Federal Power Act, FERC is
directed to assess reasonable annual charges for the use of federal
land, taking into account the act's competing goals. However, in our
view, it is difficult for FERC to make an informed decision about what
represents a reasonable annual charge without having a clear
understanding of the land's fair market value.
2. These paragraphs summarize several points that NHA raised in the
body of its comments. Our responses to these points are discussed in
the comments that follow.
3. As the report discusses, while the Federal Power Act does not
require FERC to charge fair market value, FERC has determined that fair
market value is "the most reasonable method" of compensating the
government for the use of its lands.
4. Even if we had not included 2000 in our analysis, our core findings
would remain the same--that FERC's annual charges are less than 2
percent of the fair market value of federal lands. As we recognize in
the report, 2000 was not a representative year. However, by using six
different market conditions, we ensured that our estimates would not be
overly influenced by market conditions in any single year.
5. Our report extensively discusses the potential impacts of increased
annual charges on consumers and licensees. These impacts will largely
depend on (1) how much of the land's fair market value FERC levies as
an annual charge and (2) whether the relevant project owner operates in
a regulated or restructured electricity environment. (See also comment
1.) In addition, in no case should charging fair market value for the
land result in an economic project's becoming uneconomic. A net benefit
analysis reveals the economic contributions that federal lands make to
the production of hydropower. Should FERC act at some point to capture
all or some of this value as an annual charge, economic projects will
still yield a rate of return that is at or above the industry average.
6. The net benefits method that we used is sensitive to short-term
volatility in electricity market conditions as well as to our
annualized capital cost estimates. Our estimates of a given project's
replacement cost less physical depreciation (RCLPD) may be so high that
its estimated net benefits could be negative for a low-price year, such
as 1998. A negative net benefits estimate for such a project means that
the hydropower that it produced was more expensive than the least-cost
alternative for that year. On the basis of the specific year's data, an
investor would pay zero dollars for the right to use this project's
land for hydropower generation because there are lower-cost
alternatives.
A project's negative net benefits estimate for the use of the land for
a specific year, however, does not mean that the project's land has no
value in hydropower generation. Over the lifetime of the project, the
average year's net benefits to the land may be positive owing to higher
average electricity prices. However, a negative net benefit estimate,
if accurate and representative for expected future market conditions,
would mean that the full life-cycle cost of the project is above the
current least-cost alternative. Consequently, an investor considering
building such a project today would not find it economically
feasible.[Footnote 41] Nevertheless, a consistently negative net
benefits estimate for the land in hydropower use does not mean that the
federal land has no value. It may be valuable for other uses, such as
cutting timber or grazing livestock.
It is important to reiterate, in this regard, that our 1998 estimates
are low for the western projects in our sample because 1998 wholesale
prices in the western United States were relatively low. The average
wholesale prices of electricity in the western United States are not
likely to be as low for extended periods of time in the future. Our
2003 scenario, which is based on an estimate of expected long-run
average wholesale electricity prices into the foreseeable future,
yields only four negative net benefits estimates. We also note that our
net benefits estimates for all scenarios are probably conservative
because we used capital cost estimates based on RCLPD. We used RCLPD
because we could not obtain reliable data on net book value, which is a
more appropriate measure of capital costs, given our specific method of
annualizing capital costs. RCLPD is likely to be systematically higher
than actual capital costs, resulting in lower net benefits estimates in
some cases. In addition, for three of our sample projects, we counted
all capital costs against hydropower benefits, although the projects
have other primary purposes besides hydropower generation, such as
water supply conveyance, irrigation, or flood protection. (See app. I.
for further discussion.):
7. As we state in our report, our methodology recognizes other fixed
factors of production. It compensates the owners of capital for their
capital investments at an after-tax rate of return reflecting industry
averages. Appendix I provides further details on the capital costs that
we assigned to each project's physical assets, including "(1)
reservoirs, dams and waterways, (2) power plant structures, (3) power
plant equipment, and (4) roads and bridges." The equation we use for
our net benefits estimate includes a capital depreciation factor and a
return on the capital investment based on the electric utility's
average cost of capital (for both debt and equity.) We also state in
appendix I that the appropriate variable in our equation is the net
book value (NBV) of the assets, but since NBV data were not available,
we used estimates of RCLPD. We further point out that RCLPD estimates
are "likely to be systematically higher than the amount that would
adequately compensate project owners for such costs" because RCLPD is
measured in today's dollars, while NBV is measured in historical dollar
values corresponding to the dates when the investments were made.
Consistent with economic theory and the land residual technique in the
appraisal literature, we deduct the cost of all factors of production,
including the returns to capital, from the value of hydropower in order
to obtain an estimate of the value of land used in the production of
hydropower. Land is the only fixed factor that cannot be readily
reproduced or substituted.
8. Contrary to NHA's assertion, ratepayers may not be the only group
affected by higher annual charges. Shareholders could end up paying for
higher annual charges, but only when the hydropower projects have
already been sold to private entities. As our report states:
In a restructured environment, where electricity rates are based on
wholesale market prices, increased annual charges are much more likely
to affect the profitability of the electric utility and its
shareholders than consumers. Specifically, in a restructured
environment with competition, the utility may not be able to pass on
increases in annual charges and still keep its customers. For this
reason, consumers would less likely be affected.
We agree with NHA that, in the case of divestiture, bidders for a
hydropower project are likely to offer lower bids if they think that
FERC's charges for the use of federally owned land could increase. If a
bidder is certain that FERC charges will remain low, chances are higher
that the winning bid will exceed the NBV of the project. In these
instances, states have stepped in and used sales proceeds over and
above the NBV to fund "transition credits," which lower rates to
consumers during the transition to a restructured market. We agree that
lower purchase prices for projects mean lower "transition credits" for
consumers. The trade-off is between benefits to a local utility's
consumers on the one hand and the nation's taxpayers on the other hand.
9. Traditionally, hydropower has provided consumers across the United
States with relatively low-cost electricity, and it continues to do so
despite significant rate increases in a number of western jurisdictions
following the 2000 energy crisis. We recognize that substantial
increases in annual charges for the use of federal lands could reduce
this benefit and result in adverse economic impacts under a system of
cost-based regulation. Under cost-based regulation, low charges for the
use of federal land means benefits to consumers of hydroelectric power
in the form of relatively low electricity rates, while higher charges
for the use of federal land means benefits to U.S. taxpayers in the
form of greater revenues to the federal government. In this regard, if
FERC chooses to reassess its current annual charge system, our report
recommends that FERC consider the federal land's fair market value as
well as the competing goals of encouraging hydropower development and
avoiding unreasonable rate increases to consumers.
10. We used California Power Exchange (CAPX) price data to value
hydropower produced by projects in our sample because of the integrated
nature of the wholesale electricity market in the western part of the
country, including Idaho, Montana, Oregon, and Washington State, as
well as California. Large quantities of electric power are traded
across these states. Despite occasional differences in prices for
different locations, annual averages for the price of power are
similar. Furthermore, as discussed in appendix I, we consulted with a
number of experts--including experts from the Northwest Power Planning
Council, the California Independent System Operator, and the Idaho
Public Utility Commission--on this matter, and they agreed that it is
reasonable to use the annual average of hourly prices in California as
a proxy for the annual average price for the entire Northwest region.
11. See comment 1. Furthermore, operation and maintenance costs were
among the least difficult data for us to collect in our analysis. As
discussed in appendix I, hydropower licensees routinely report these
costs on either FERC Form 1 or EIA Form 412.
12. We used combined-cycle combustion turbine (CCCT) technology as the
most likely alternative generating source because it is widely, if not
universally, recognized as the least-cost alternative to run-of-river
hydropower projects. In numerous meetings with industry
representatives, where we presented our methodology and findings in
detail, there were few, if any, objections to our assumption that the
CCCT technology was the least-cost alternative to hydropower
generation. In these meetings, we pointed out that our assumption is
actually a conservative one. Some hydropower projects are used as peak-
load resources, for which the alternative is a simple combustion
turbine, whose life-cycle cost per kilowatt-hour is considerably
higher. We also recognize that CCCT costs will vary with the price of
fuel.
In addition, contrary to NHA's assertion, there is always an
alternative to any existing source of power generation at some price.
The more expensive the alternative, the higher the net benefits
estimate for the hydropower project.
13. As discussed in comment 7, we carefully considered the value of the
plant and equipment used by the hydropower projects in our sample. As
discussed in appendix I, our methodology fully compensates project
owners for these investments by subtracting as a cost (1) an annual
depreciation factor and (2) a return on investment. We determined the
return on investment by multiplying the project's RCLPD by 7.22
percent--which is the after-tax weighted cost of capital for investor-
owned utilities estimated by Global Insight for 1998 and 2002. This
rate is also consistent with guidance from the Office of Management and
Budget. As we discussed in comment 7, our methodology probably
overcompensates project owners because it uses RCLPD instead of the
lower net book value of the utility's assets.
Like all capital investments that regulated utilities undertake,
hydropower projects were developed with the certainty that owners would
recover their costs (commonly referred to as "rate base") and earn a
rate of return determined by state regulators. Risks to capital
investments in such a "regulated monopoly" environment are generally
considered lower than they are for entrepreneurs operating in a
competitive, unregulated environment.
14. FERC decides what lands are required to be included within the
boundaries of hydropower projects. Some lands are used to generate
hydropower, while others are included to meet other objectives of the
Federal Power Act--such as mitigating the negative impacts that
hydropower may create. We did not try to distinguish between lands that
meet varying purposes of the law. Rather, we relied on decisions that
FERC made--and the licensee agreed to--regarding the lands that were
necessary to operate each project. Furthermore, with regard to the
public's receiving other benefits from the project's operation on these
lands, these benefits are also a condition of obtaining a license from
FERC. (Also see comment 18.):
15. Vanceburg was decided about 26 years ago. Since then, FERC has
determined that a "national average rental value," discussed with
approval in Vanceburg, is not the most reasonable method for
determining annual charges. In fact, on pages 16 and 17 of its
comments, NHA acknowledges that FERC has recognized that a national
average rental value is no longer an appropriate measure for annual
charges. (See also comment 1.):
16. We agree that comparable sales data are the best indicator of land
value, but we disagree that applicable comparable sales data exist for
federal lands within the boundaries of hydropower projects. The Uniform
Standards for Federal Land Acquisitions provide that income-based
valuation methods may be used where comparable sales data are lacking.
The condemnation cases NHA cites did not address FERC's authority to
establish annual charges under section 10(e) of the Federal Power Act
and FERC made no reference to them in discussing its 10(e) authority in
the 1987 rule making. FERC has stated that the most reasonable method
for basing annual charges is fair market value, and that charges should
be proportionate with the benefits conveyed. Therefore, the report
recommends that FERC reassess its annual charge system for the use of
federal lands. In doing so, the report also recommends that FERC
determine methods for (1) estimating the fair market value of these
lands and (2) assessing annual charges--taking into account the
competing goals of the Federal Power Act.
NHA has asserted that lands within project boundaries must be valued
according to their last use before they were included in the project.
However, courts have held that these lands may be valued for power
purposes. For example, in United States v. Pend Oreille PUD No. 1. 28
F.3d 1544 (9th Cir. 1994), cert. denied 514 U.S. 1015 (1995), the court
held that the measure of damages for a project's unauthorized
inundation of tribal lands was the value of the land for power
production purposes. (Id. at 1551.):
For our purpose of estimating the fair market value of the land used to
produce hydropower, prices of adjacent agricultural lands, for example,
do not constitute useful comparables. The compensation that a landowner
receives in a condemnation procedure also does not shed light on the
value of land in hydropower generation for a similar reason because
condemnation, by definition, is not a transaction between two willing
parties.
17. The Federal Power Act states that FERC shall "seek to avoid"
increases in consumer electricity rates. FERC has interpreted this
provision to prohibit unreasonable charges that would be passed along
to consumers--but not to prohibit all charges that would result in rate
increases.
18. FERC has twice rejected NHA's assertion that potential annual
charges for the use of federal land should be adjusted to recognize the
public benefits provided by hydropower projects, such as recreation,
flood control, irrigation, and fish and wildlife enhancement. Section
10(a) of the Federal Power Act requires FERC to determine, as a
condition of issuing a license, that the project will be best adapted
to a comprehensive plan for waterway development "and for other
beneficial uses, including recreational purposes." In 1977 FERC stated:
The argument that a licensee may reduce its statutory obligation to pay
charges for the use of lands of the United States by offsetting the
value of certain benefits provided, when the licensee's right to
construct, maintain, and operate its project depends in part on the
provision of such benefits, is untenable. The "remuneration" to the
licensee, if any is due, for providing these benefits is the
Commission's permission to operate the project; no further
compensation, in the form of a credit to annual charge levies is due or
owing.[Footnote 42]
FERC reaffirmed this conclusion in its 1987 annual charge rule making.
In short, under the Federal Power Act, public benefits are provided as
a condition of receiving the license, and the licensee deserves no
compensation for merely complying with the law.
19. We do not believe that the Forest Service's rights-of-way fee
system--on which the FERC annual charge system is based--is consistent
with sound appraisal practices. We discussed the significant flaws of
the Forest Service fee system for rights-of-way and refer to our 1996
report, where we examined this system in detail.[Footnote 43] In short,
the Forest Service stated that its rights-of-way system was not getting
fair market value for rights-of-way. In fact, according to Forest
Service officials, this system may be getting as little as 10 percent
of the value for federal lands used for rights-of-way.
In addition, lands used for rights-of-way are generally long, narrow
corridors that accommodate power lines, pipelines, or communication
lines. These lands contrast significantly with lands capable of
producing hydropower, which may include large masses of land that can
be as wide as a large river or large lake. Furthermore, lands suitable
for rights-of-way are relatively common, while lands suitable for
hydropower are scarce. Thus, we do not believe that the use of the
Forest Service's rights-of-way system is consistent with sound
appraisal practices in determining the fair market value of lands
capable of producing hydropower.
20. We believe that our analysis is consistent with generally accepted
appraisal practices. As we discuss in our report, we could not use the
comparable sales approach because there is no active market in lands
rented for hydropower purposes. As discussed in our report, FERC
requires licensees, as a condition of obtaining a license, to own the
lands within the boundary of the projects or obtain an easement in
perpetuity from another landowner. (Federal lands and lands within
Indian reservations are not subject to this requirement.) As a result,
we used a net benefits approach to determine the value of federal lands
used to produce hydropower. This approach is similar to the income
approach, which bases the value of property on its income-producing
potential. Appraisal guidance indicates that in cases where no active
market exists, a forecast of expected cash flows may aid in estimating
the value of assets, provided the expected cash flows are discounted at
a rate proportionate with the risk involved.[Footnote 44] We
essentially took this approach and modified it by using wholesale
market prices to value hydropower instead of cost-based utility
revenues. (See app I.) Our net benefits approach is grounded in
economic principles that form the basis of the "land residual
technique," detailed in The Appraisal of Real Estate--a widely accepted
publication on appraisal practices.[Footnote 45]
21. As we stated in comment 1, we do not specifically recommend that
FERC adopt the net benefits approach as a means for assessing annual
charges. In addition, FERC would have to factor in administrative costs
into any decision it makes in revising its current annual charge
system. Furthermore, while it took us nearly 3 years to complete and
publish our analysis, FERC could likely perform its own analysis much
more quickly because it has (1) more experience than we did with
performing this type of analysis, (2) hydropower-engineering expertise
on staff (we did not and had to contract out for this expertise), and
(3) detailed information on electricity markets (we spent time and
resources collecting this type of information).
22. As mentioned in comment 1, we used our methodology as a tool to
value the federal lands used for hydropower generation. Our
recommendation is for FERC to consider fair market value in setting
charges for the use of federal land, but we do not prescribe a specific
method for setting charges. If FERC desires, a system of annual charges
can be designed to vary little from year-to-year and could exclude the
effects of a year such as 2000, which our report recognizes as an
outlier.
23. While the Federal Power Act may preclude unilateral changes in
license terms and conditions, the act does not preclude FERC from
changing its annual charge system. We note that FERC currently adjusts
charges for most licenses from year to year under its current system.
These adjustments reflect the Forest Service's annual updating of its
fee system for rights-of-way.
24. We recognize that FERC will have to consider a number of policy
goals if it decides to reassess its current annual charge system. Even
though NHA asserts that revising annual charges will go against some
policy concerns raised in the Congress and the executive branch, we
note that the Subcommittee on Energy and Water Development,
House Committee on Appropriations--which oversees FERC's
appropriations--has instructed the commission to consider
making changes to its annual charge system. Specifically, in the
report that accompanied FERC's fiscal year 2003 appropriations, the
Committee stated:
The General Accounting Office (GAO) has underway an analysis of the
land rents charged by FERC for non-federal hydropower projects located
on federal lands. Preliminary results from GAO indicate that the fee
schedule presently used by FERC significantly underestimates, possibly
by as much as two orders of magnitude, the fair market value of these
project lands used for non-federal hydropower. The Committee directs
FERC to submit a proposal to Congress that will revise the existing fee
schedule to a new methodology that will capture more of the real market
value of these federal lands.[Footnote 46]
25. While FERC declined to adopt the net benefits methodology as a
mechanism for establishing annual charges, FERC approved an indexed
charge, on the basis of values derived from the net benefits
methodology.
26. See comments 1 and 4. In addition, there is nothing unusual about
using a technique that is similar to the income approach to value land.
The income approach is a widely accepted appraisal practice.
27. We disagree. As noted in Vanceburg, a tax is imposed by the
sovereign without regard to choice or particular benefit. By contrast,
an annual charge is a fee paid by choice in exchange for a particular
benefit.[Footnote 47] Furthermore, FERC has recognized that annual
charges should be proportionate to the benefit conferred and that fair
market value is the most reasonable method to measure that benefit.
28. The map presented in NHA's comments demonstrates that many states
have considered or undergone significant change in restructuring their
electricity markets since FERC issued its annual charge regulations in
1987.[Footnote 48] In addition, as our report states, FERC's current
policy is to encourage greater competition in all wholesale energy
markets. Given the amount of change in electricity markets that has
occurred and the potential for additional change, we believe that it is
time for FERC to reassess its current annual charge system so that,
among other things, it reflects the current electricity environment.
29. As the report discusses, the Federal Power Act has several goals,
including the development of hydropower, the prohibition against
unreasonable rate increases, and the compensation of the United States
for the use of its lands.
[End of section]
Appendix V: Comments from the Department of the Interior:
United States Department of the Interior:
OFFICE OF THE SECRETARY Washington, D.C. 20240:
APR 3 2003:
Mr. Barry Hill:
Director, Natural Resources and Environment U.S. General Accounting
Office:
441 G Street, NW Washington, DC 20548:
Dear Mr. Hill:
The Department of the Interior has reviewed the General Accounting
Office's (GAO) draft report entitled, "Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission: Charges for Hydropower Projects' Use of Federal Lands Need
to Be Reassessed" (GAO-03-383). Generally the Department agrees with
the findings of the draft report. You have structured the problem well
and conducted an important piece of research. We hope that your study
will lead to improvements in public policy.
The Department agrees that FERC should reconsider its current system
and develop strategies and options for assessing annual charges that
are commensurate with the economic benefits conveyed to hydropower
licensees. In reconsidering its current system, FERC should consult
with affected licensees, agencies, Indian tribes, and other
stakeholders.
The Department further agrees that improvements can be made in
identifying and verifying the amount of federal lands hydropower
projects use. The Department supports a recent FERC proposal to improve
and standardize basic project boundary information submitted by license
applicants (Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, February 20, 2003, 103 FERC
61,185). In addition, the Department offers to work with FERC in
verifying the accounting of federal lands currently occupied by FERC-
licensed projects.
The Department understands that you chose to focus your study on annual
charges that are returned to the U.S. Treasury, and therefore excluded
from this analysis annual charges returned to Indian tribes pursuant to
Section 17(a) of the Federal Power Act. The Department notes that your
findings apply equally to annual charges for Indian lands.
Additional comments and technical corrections are enclosed.
Sincerely,
P. Lynn Scarlett
Assistant Secretary Policy, Management, and Budget:
Signed by P. Lynn Scarlett:
Enclosure:
ENCLOSURE:
Additional Comments and Technical Corrections:
p 1. Footnote 1 needs to explicitly state that Indian reservations were
excluded from the definition of "federal lands." It may also be useful
to state what the number of projects would be if Indian reservations
were included in the definition.
p. 7 "about 173 of which use at least some federal lands." This
statement is inconsistent with the figures in footnote 1. Either change
173 to 281, or change the statement to "about 173 of which use 25 or
more acres of federal lands.":
p. 11 It should be noted that there is an inherent difference between
the "linear rights-of-way" fees assessed by the Bureau of Land
Management and the US Forest Service, and the "single user" fees
assessed by FERC. Linear rights-of-way allow a single, non-exclusive
use of the federal lands. The same land may be used for other purposes,
including other rights-of-way, at the discretion of the land management
agency, without prior approval of the right-of-way holder. By contrast,
a hydropower facility is typically granted exclusive use, or at least
prior approval for other uses.
p. 37 "Our net benefits methodology, like the land residual technique,
starts with the value of the goods that are produced and then subtracts
the costs of all nonland factors of production. The residual net
benefits are the estimated value of the land.":
It should be noted that potential land rent (the price for the use of
federal land for a specific time period) is not equal to the total
economic rent (payments in excess of those necessary to attract a
resource to the production of the product), but a portion of it
determined by the cost of the next higher cost alternative means of
producing power (see figure below). Under competitive economic
conditions, no rational investor would pay more than the difference
between the long-run marginal cost of generating power at the next-
cheapest alternative source for power (Ca) and the long-run marginal
cost (sans land rent) of generating power at the hydropower facility
(Ch) for land rent for a hydropower facility.
If the rent were greater than Ca Ch a cost-minimizing investor
considering whether to invest in and generate power with a hydropower
facility versus investing in and generating power with the next-
cheapest alternative source will select the alternative source. Thus,
under competitive conditions, land rent is determined by the generating
cost of the next higher cost unit.
ENCLOSURE:
If one were to use the difference between the expected wholesale price
for power (P) and the long-run marginal cost (sans land rent) of
generating power at the hydropower facility to determine land rent, you
would overpay the rent for land, i.e., pay more than the competitively
determined amount. This difference,
P-Ch,
is the sum of land rent and the economic rent (excess profit per kwh)
for the hydropower facility. The only exception to this occurs when the
hydropower facility is the marginal facility in the region. In that
case, competition would indeed result in a land rent of P - Ch, and
economic rent would be zero.
[See PDF for image]
[End of figure]
p. 45 Replace the symbol "R" in the definition section with the symbol
"r" which appears in the formula.
p. 47 In the text, change operations and maintenance costs, including a
share of the project owner's overhead costs should be changed from $25
million to $20 million to match the numbers in Table 5.
The following are GAO's comments on the Department of the Interior's
letter dated April 3, 2003.
GAO's Comments:
1. We revised the first footnote to state that we did not include
Indian reservations in our definition of federal lands.
2. For greater clarity, we added a footnote regarding the number of
hydropower projects that use federal lands.
3. Our report discusses a number of flaws associated with using a fee
system designed for rights-of-way to collect annual charges for
hydropower uses. For the reasons discussed in the report, we believe it
is difficult for FERC to defend its continued use of the current annual
charge system. In its comments, the Department of the Interior observes
yet another flaw--that federal lands used for rights-of-way remain
available for most other uses, while federal lands licensed for use in
hydropower projects in many cases do not. This is another reason for
FERC to reassess its current annual charge system and consider making
revisions.
4. The Department of the Interior argued that land rent in a
competitive market that is stable in the long run cannot exceed the
per-kilowatt cost differential between hydropower and the least-cost
alternative for new capacity. Given the Department of the Interior's
assumption of a long-term competitive equilibrium, we agree with this
principle and believe that our valuation methodology is consistent with
this approach while focusing on the more concrete but variable
realization of land values in the shorter term. In practice, the price
may be different from the incremental cost of a long-term alternative
owing to various market conditions, such as when there are few, if any,
options to the spot wholesale market for electricity. For example, to
the extent that 2000 prices reflect the exercise of market power in
California, they yield estimates of land values that are too high and
cannot be sustained. In the longer term, low-cost alternatives, such as
new production facilities based on natural gas or coal, would limit the
value of the land to the cost differential between hydropower and these
alternatives. Given the evolving state of the wholesale market for
electricity, we chose to estimate fair market value on the basis of as
much observable data as possible, while the analysis for 2003 embodies
the principle that the market prices move to the price of the least-
cost alternative in the long run.
[End of section]
Appendix VI: GAO Contact and Staff Acknowledgments:
GAO Contact:
Ned Woodward (202) 512-8051:
Acknowledgments:
In addition to the individual named above, Robert J. Aiken, Paul
Aussendorf, Karen Bracey, Carol Bray, Sandra Cantler, Allen Chan,
Mark Connelly, Charlie Cotton, Philip Farah, Scott Farrow, Richard
Johnson, Chester Joy, Joseph Kile, Frank Kovalak, Penny Pickett,
Carol Herrnstadt Shulman, Donna Weiss, Arvin Wu, and James Yeager made
key contributions to this report.
(141460):
FOOTNOTES
[1] For this report, we focused on the 173 projects that use 25 acres
or more of federal land to produce hydropower. An additional 109
projects use fewer than 25 acres of federal land to produce hydropower.
Also, we did not include projects that only use federal lands for the
transmission of power. Finally, we did not include Indian reservations
in our definition of federal lands.
[2] The capitalized value of the land is the present value of the
expected annual net benefits over the future lifetime of the project.
[3] See 48 Fed. Reg. 15134, 15136 (1983).
[4] For this report, we focused on the 173 projects that use 25 acres
or more of federal land to produce hydropower.
[5] Our review did not focus on FERC's administration of its
responsibilities under section 10(e) of the Federal Power Act to
establish annual charges for hydropower projects occupying lands within
Indian reservations.
[6] See 52 Fed. Reg. 18201, 18205 (1987).
[7] See Department of Energy, Assessment of Charges Under The
Hydropower Licensing Program, DOE/IG-0178 (Dec. 22, 1981).
[8] See U.S. General Accounting Office, U.S. Forest Service: Fee System
for Rights-of-Way Program Needs Revision (GAO/RCED-96-84,
Apr. 22, 1996).
[9] See U.S. General Accounting Office, Standards for Internal Control
in the Federal Government (1999).
[10] In this context, market power refers to the ability of individual
sellers of electricity to charge prices above competitive levels. For
more information on the electricity market in California, see U.S.
General Accounting Office, Restructured Electricity
Markets: California Market Design Enabled Exercise of Market Power,
GAO-02-828, (June 21, 2002).
[11] For greater detail on how we determined costs for this analysis,
see app. I.
[12] For our estimate of the return on investment for each project, see
app. II.
[13] Over the long-term, a combined-cycle combustion turbine (CCCT)
technology, that primarily utilizes natural gas as a fuel, is generally
considered the lowest cost alternative for electric power from a
hydropower project that runs most of the time. Significant changes
in the relative prices of fossil fuels could make another technology
more economic. For example, if gas prices are expected to rise
significantly, a coal-fired power plant technology may supplant CCCT as
the lowest-cost alternative. However, this would make hydropower
relatively more valuable.
[14] Three of these five projects were built for purposes other than
hydropower, such as irrigation, one had high capital costs, and one had
less than 1 percent of its project on federal lands.
[15] According to Idaho Power's annual report (SEC Form 10-K405) for
the fiscal year ending Dec 31, 2001, the cost of operating Idaho Power
for 1999 was about $546 million. Once adjusted to 2002 dollars--which
we did for comparison purposes--the $546 million becomes $580 million.
[16] In restructured markets, hydropower owners will be free to sell
the electricity they generate at market prices, rather than at
regulated rates. However, they will not be able to sell electricity
above the market price.
[17] As states regulate electricity markets, they also act on behalf of
state ratepayers in approving the final restructuring arrangements. In
some cases, the restructuring arrangements will then result in states'
capturing some or all of the net benefit of projects that are sold as
part of a restructuring effort.
[18] 48 Fed. Reg. 15134, 15136 (1983).
[19] See The Appraisal of Real Estate, 12th ed. (Chicago: Appraisal
Institute, 2001), especially pp. 25 to 26 and ch. V. Even when market
sales are available, a complete appraisal requires the use of all
available information as well as market sales.
[20] This technique goes back to David Ricardo's notion that "land rent
is a residual, equal to the excess of revenues from the sale of goods
produced on the land over remunerations to non-land factors used in
production." Cited in Norman G. Miller, Steven T. Jones, and Stephen E.
Roulac, "In Defense of the Land Residual Theory and the Absence of a
Business Value Component for Retail Property," The Journal of Real
Estate Research 10:2 (1995): 203-15. This article gives a brief review
of other economists who advanced this theory into the 1990s.
[21] See, for example, Richard C. Zuker and Glenn P. Jenkins, Blue
Gold: Hydro-Electric Rents in Canada, a study prepared for the Economic
Council of Canada (Ottawa: Canadian Government Publishing Centre,
1984), Eirik S. Amundsen, Christian Andersen, and Jan Gaute Saunnarnes,
"Rent Taxes on Norwegian Hydropower Generation," The Energy Journal
13:1 (1992), and David Gillen and Jean-Francois Wen, Waterpower Program
Financial Review, report submitted to Ontario Ministry of Natural
Resources, Province of Ontario, (April 1997.)
[22] The implementation of the Norwegian methodology differs from ours
in that it capitalizes net benefits over the entire lifetime of the
project; our approach relies on annualized net benefits calculations.
The capitalization approach assumes adequate knowledge of hydropower
values and costs in the future. We refrained from such an approach
because we wished to avoid forecasting values and costs well into the
future.
[23] Some project owners have argued that land within a project
boundary that does not contribute anything to hydropower generation
should not be valued for hydropower purposes. However, the project
owner could not have obtained its license without gaining access to all
the land within the project boundary; thus, it is inaccurate to argue
that there is no relationship between the federal land within the
boundary and the hydropower project. Moreover, FERC established the
project boundaries as containing those lands.
[24] East Columbia Basin Irrigation District v. FERC, 946 F.2d 1550,
1560 (9th Cir. 1991). Licensees also argue that if land is to be valued
on the basis of its contribution to hydropower production, each acre
should be assessed differently, so that acres included in the project
solely for environmental purposes, for example, are assessed at a lower
rate. In response, we note that FERC's current system of land charge
also assesses the same charge for each acre within the project
boundary, regardless of the individual acre's contribution to
hydropower production. In any event, the licensees can obtain no
economic benefit from the project unless it obtains access to all the
lands within the project boundary. However, FERC is authorized to
approve licensee requests to alter project boundaries. Such requests
could increase in the event that significant increases in annual
charges, undifferentiated by acre, were to be implemented.
[25] To create a value that is comparable to current annual FERC
charges, we focused on the annual value of the lands in a hydropower
project. This is different from the capitalized value of the project's
land. The capitalized value is the present value of annual net benefits
over the future lifetime of the project. An appraiser would consider
the capitalized value of the land in connection with an outright sale
of the land, for example, as opposed to annual charges for the use of
the land.
[26] A standard definition of revenue requirements is
where
= total quantity of revenues to be provided,
= total operating costs of the firm,
= depreciation allowance,
= allowed rate of return on the firm's undepreciated assets, and
= net value of the firm's undepreciated assets, or the rate base.
See Giles Burgess Jr., The Economics of Regulation and Antitrust (New
York: HarperCollins College Publishers, 1995), p. 66.
[27] The electricity generation capacity of a power plant is measured
in kilowatts, or megawatts. One kilowatt is 1,000 watts, and a megawatt
is 1 million watts. A watt is an electrical unit of power, or rate of
energy transfer.
[28] These figures exclude land used for transmitting electric power.
[29] Wholesale electric power prices vary from one hour of the day to
the next.
[30] Sensitivity analysis refers to artificially changing the value of
a given variable in a model to gauge the effect of change on model
results.
[31] We adjusted all dollar values in our analysis to 2002 constant
dollars, using the gross domestic product (GDP) implicit price
deflator.
[32] These are prices for SERC, excluding Florida. We obtained them
from the Tennessee Valley Authority, but they originate from Power
Markets Weekly.
[33] The California Aqueduct project also includes a pumped-storage
facility, but we did not treat the project as a whole as a pumped
storage facility.
[34] A pumped water project pumps water from a lower reservoir to an
upper reservoir at times when demand for electricity is low. During
periods of high demand, the water is released back to generate
electricity. For 1998 and 1999, we calculated a weighted average value
per megawatt-hour for Dominion Virginia Power sales from BCPS at $34.03
and $51.98, respectively. These values are 1.57 and 1.86 times higher
than the simple averages of hourly PJM-WH prices for these years. We
used the lower of these two ratios, 1.57, as an escalation factor for
the 2000 simple average of hourly PJM-WH prices to value BCPS
generation for that year.
[35] Base load generating plants are designed for nearly continuous
operation at or near full capacity to provide all or part of the base
load. Base load is the minimum level of demand for electric power in a
given system over a period of time.
[36] Global Insight World Energy Service, U.S. Outlook, released
January 2002.
[37] Ancillary services are required to maintain system reliability and
meet the electric system's operating criteria. They include spinning,
nonspinning, replacement reserves, regulation, voltage control, and
instantaneous start capability.
[38] Net book value is defined as original cost less accumulated
depreciation--all in the dollar values of the years in which the
original costs were incurred.
[39] According to OMB Circular A-94, "Guidelines and Discount Rates for
Benefit-Cost Analysis of Federal Programs," the real (constant dollar)
rate of 7 percent "approximates the marginal pretax rate of return on
an average investment in the private sector in recent years." Investor-
owned electric utilities, however, belong to the corporate segment of
the private sector. According to the Office of Management and Budget,
the private, real pretax rate of return on an average investment in the
corporate private sector over the period 1991 through 2001 has been
about 10 percent, making an after-tax rate of about 7 percent a
reasonable estimate for the corporate sector. The level of financial
risk in the regulated electric utility industry has generally been
lower, so historical rates of return were probably also lower than the
average for the corporate sector. However, unregulated energy companies
that operate in today's restructured electricity markets face higher
risk levels than their regulated counterparts did in the past.
[40] The manager of BCPS told us that the relationship between the
amount of electricity used for pumping water and the amount of
hydropower it generates is stable over time: 1.25 kilowatt-hours of
pumping are needed for each kilowatt-hour of power generated, on
average. We also calculated the average cost of pumping per kilowatt-
hour for 1998 and 1999, using hourly amounts of electricity used for
pumping and hourly PJM-WH prices. For those 2 years, we calculated a
ratio of this weighted average cost of pumping to the simple annual
average of hourly PJM-WH prices. We used these relationships and BCPS'
2000 and 2003 hydropower generation figures to extrapolate the
project's 2000 and 2003 pumping costs.
[41] Many hydropower projects were built decades ago under different
economic circumstances. Some projects may or may not be considered
economically feasible under today's economic conditions. If an existing
project would not be considered economically feasible today, it may
still be profitable for the original owner or a future buyer. The
majority of capital costs for most projects were incurred decades ago,
and project owners are likely to have been largely compensated for
these costs at rates of return set by regulators.
[42] 42 Fed. Reg. 1229 (1977).
[43] See U.S. General Accounting Office, U.S. Forest Service: Fee
System for Rights-of-Way Program Needs Revision (GAO/RCED-96-84, Apr.
22, 1996).
[44] See Appraisal Standards Board Advisory Opinion 8 (AO-8).
[45] See The Appraisal of Real Estate, 12th ed. (Chicago: Appraisal
Institute: 2001,) pp. 539-543.
[46] H. R. Rep. No. 107-681 (2002).
[47] City of Vanceburg v. FERC, 571 F.2d 630, 644 n.48 (D.C Cir. 1977).
[48] This map may be viewed in color by going to www.eia.doe.gov/cneaf/
electricity/chg_str/regmap.html.
GAO's Mission:
The General Accounting Office, the investigative arm of Congress,
exists to support Congress in meeting its constitutional
responsibilities and to help improve the performance and accountability
of the federal government for the American people. GAO examines the use
of public funds; evaluates federal programs and policies; and provides
analyses, recommendations, and other assistance to help Congress make
informed oversight, policy, and funding decisions. GAO's commitment to
good government is reflected in its core values of accountability,
integrity, and reliability.
Obtaining Copies of GAO Reports and Testimony:
The fastest and easiest way to obtain copies of GAO documents at no
cost is through the Internet. GAO's Web site ( www.gao.gov ) contains
abstracts and full-text files of current reports and testimony and an
expanding archive of older products. The Web site features a search
engine to help you locate documents using key words and phrases. You
can print these documents in their entirety, including charts and other
graphics.
Each day, GAO issues a list of newly released reports, testimony, and
correspondence. GAO posts this list, known as "Today's Reports," on its
Web site daily. The list contains links to the full-text document
files. To have GAO e-mail this list to you every afternoon, go to
www.gao.gov and select "Subscribe to daily E-mail alert for newly
released products" under the GAO Reports heading.
Order by Mail or Phone:
The first copy of each printed report is free. Additional copies are $2
each. A check or money order should be made out to the Superintendent
of Documents. GAO also accepts VISA and Mastercard. Orders for 100 or
more copies mailed to a single address are discounted 25 percent.
Orders should be sent to:
U.S. General Accounting Office
441 G Street NW,
Room LM Washington,
D.C. 20548:
To order by Phone:
Voice: (202) 512-6000:
TDD: (202) 512-2537:
Fax: (202) 512-6061:
To Report Fraud, Waste, and Abuse in Federal Programs:
Contact:
Web site: www.gao.gov/fraudnet/fraudnet.htm E-mail: fraudnet@gao.gov
Automated answering system: (800) 424-5454 or (202) 512-7470:
Public Affairs:
Jeff Nelligan, managing director, NelliganJ@gao.gov (202) 512-4800 U.S.
General Accounting Office, 441 G Street NW, Room 7149 Washington, D.C.
20548: